What Is Wrong With Globalization? | Economics for People with Ha-Joon Chang

Video Statistics and Information

Video
Captions Word Cloud
Reddit Comments
Captions
(mysterious music) - The most shocking recent political event for lots of people was the election of Mr. Trump who with the most powerful political office in the world, despite having zero experience in politics. That happened in November 2016 but earlier that year the British electorate decided to take the country out of the European Union. In a number of countries in the rich world their really kind of a anti-foreign, right-wing politics have come to prominence. The Netherlands, in Finland, in Denmark, in Sweden, in Austria, countries that have been traditionally associated with center-left, sort of liberal values, and this has made a lot of people ask Christians about why this is happening? The supporters of these anti-foreign, anti-immigrant parties are often described as angry people. People who are angry because they have been left behind in the evolution of the global economy in the last few decades. Now the talk on globalization was invented by an American business school professor, whose name no one remembers now. We invent concepts and thoughts all the time to describe new things and it is one of those. But suddenly in the 1990's it took off and at least since the mid 1990's, it has been the defining concept over time. The basic definition of globalization is increased flow of goods, services, capital, people, although, all of the people who talk about globalization try not to talk about immigration. Because it's a politically sensitive issue and people who are gung ho about great to open there stores up, goods and capital are not very positive about opening borders for people. So that's an interesting kind of inconsistency but that is now kind of more comprehensive by definition, which says, it's not just about increased flows but also about changing global rules. Now it is, in terms of rules, are sometimes force countries to change their domestic rules as well. Because sometimes it's just about not having tariff. Not putting special conditions for foreign investors, that's more straight forward but now, this universe of rules, the idea has spread so much that now countries are expected to change their corporate accounting practices to fit with these western practices. They have been expected to change their rules on patterns, government procurement, lots of things that we had thought were not the subject to, international globalization in our coming under this set of common rules. The impact is much greater than just border control, if you like. Now according to the dominant discourse globalization happens because of technology. Technology is about communications, transportation, that have become a lot more developed with the digital technology, now even information can be moved around so, when you do, I don't know, MRI scan of a patient in Boston, you can send it to actually India so that someone can read it there at a much lower wage rate and send it back. These technological changes have created, in popular expression, the death of distance, distance doesn't matter anymore. This has enabled us to deploy resources where they have the highest productivity. We are not bound by national borders anymore and until they were wrong-footed by the 2008 financial crisis, many of our political leaders and leading economist, names like Jagdish Bhagwati and Jeffrey Sachs come to mind, was singing praises of globalization. Robert Rubin who was the U.S. Treasury Secretary or what would be called Finance Minister in other countries because of globalization and open market and the spread of market-based systems, the world is a much better place. Kofi Annan was even more enthused about this, saying that this not just about prosperity in the rich countries but the only realistic way of pulling billions of people out of poverty. This was like trying to fight against the law of gravity or Robert McCormick, the chairman of the International Chamber of Commerce said in 2003, World Economic Forum Davos, people trying to stop this was against progress and Mr McCormick deliberately likened, that the anti-globalization protestors that were shouting outside his venues in Davos, look these are like the Luddites. Luddites are this English textile artisans who lost their jobs to textile machines in the early 19th century and, at least some of them thought, they could bring their jobs back if they destroyed the machines. So they have become the byword for people who are fighting the inevitable, trying to turn the clock back. And Mr. McCormick was saying, you are against globalization, you are basically against progress. So there was a lot of confidence that this process will bring prosperity, lift people up out of poverty, this is a unique chance for humanity to leap to the next level, and they recommended therefore, countries need to open up their borders. The most immediate one was trade liberalization, so reduce tariffs, ideally abolish it but you might need some revenue from it. So reduce it to a low level, get rid of quantitative restrictions like quotas. In addition to trade, investment was also liberalized. Previously there was lots of restrictions on how much foreigners can invest in the financial market and what kind of assets they can acquire. I mean, many of these regulations have been abolished, so now there were huge financial flows coming into the so-called emerging markets. Basically, middle income countries which use to have the CBO restrictions on financial flows. Poorer countries are cautious about liberalizing finance capital but a lot of them embrace the foreign direct investment. So foreign direct investment is like, actually there is no agreed analytical definition because it basically means someone acquiring a stake and a say in management in a company that does production activity within your national border and that someone happens to be a foreigner. Now sometimes it's what people call Greenfield investment, so enter, out of the blue, comes into Costa Rica and builds a microchip factory but it could be also what people call Brownfield investment. There's some ailing car company in Turkey and Volkswagen comes and buys it up, now this kind of investment has been particularly praised for stability and also it's ability to provide technology as well as finance capital. Until the 80's, 90's, a lot of countries has restrictions on what foreign investors could do. So, there would be rules on which sectors they can invest, there would be sectors that would be completely closed off to foreigners. There might be a requirement that the majority owner should be a local. Countries could say, well you have to source more than 50% of input are from local produces, the ratio going up to 85% in 10 years. These kind of conditions are very common but now all other countries have abolished this in an attempt to attract foreign capital, especially in the foreign direct investment. Many of them have also changed their domestic policy to create what you feminist call, a business friendly environment. They'll cut corporate tax rate, reduce workers right so that foreign companies can exploit them more readily, deregulate business and this has changed a policy regimens in many countries. Having made this recommendations, the proponents of this path admitted that yes, in the short run there might be some losers from the process. So and that the U.S. opens up this automobile market or signs a Free Trade Agreement with Mexico, this might make some local auto workers to lose jobs because there would be more imports from say Korea. Some of the American companies might relocate some of their factories from Mexico. These things have happened but the argument was that yes, in the short run this will happen but in the long run these people will be actually better off because in the long run they'll be doing much better paying jobs. Because with this liberalization and the free trade agreement the U.S will be exporting more investment banking services or software to countries like Korea and Mexico. Therefore, these people will eventually get jobs that are better and better paying than the ones they used to have. That is the theory, in reality, how many former auto workers in the United States who have turned themselves into IT engineers, not to speak of investment bankers? One very striking evidence is that in the United States the median, not the average, median wage has been basically stagnate since the mid 1970's, despite the fact that the countries real per capita income that is inflation or just per capita income has more than doubled during that period. Now why do people get left behind in this process? The short answer is because it's costly to get retrained. Yeah, in theory you could become an investment banker but that might mean going back to the college, doing a masters degree and doing lots of jobs before you can get hired by investment banking company. Very few people have the resources and time and perseverance to do that. So as a result, only a small number of people who got unemployed through these changes have been employed in jobs that are better paying than what they were doing before. Most of them are either languishing in long term unemployment or have ended up in low skilled jobs, like security guard, shelf stacking in the super market or male stripping as in the British movie The Full Monty. It is a movie about six unemployed Sheffield steel workers or rather, ex- steel workers. So in technical terms, in the standard model of international trade known as Heckscher- Ohlin- Samuelson model. Named after two Swedish economists of the early 20th century and later Paul Samuelson, the economists who sold the largest number of textbooks in the history of economics between the 1950's and 80's. Samuelson formalized what Heckscher and Ohlin theorized in the early 20th century and this is the standard theory that is used to defend free trade. Like all theories it makes lots of assumptions and one of the critical assumptions there is full factor mobility. This means that capital labor can be easily transferred to other sectors if the demand for the original sectors fall. So if the demand for auto workers fall and people move into investment banking. If American steel industry goes down somehow you can remold these steel mill into a factory that produces microchips. Put in this way, sounds ridiculous but that is the theoretical assumption behind this model and basically when that assumption doesn't hold, you have this phenomenon about people being left behind. Defenders of globalization have argued that essentially there is acceleration of growth from this process, which will create more wealth, which will then trickle down to the bottom eventually. So its a matter of adjustment, it will happen in the end. Now despite the bad press that it often gets, trickle down is not necessarily a stupid theory. What it is saying is that, you have to look at second or even third round effects of something. For the simple fact that trade literally has made some American workers lose their jobs doesn't necessarily mean that there would be worst off in the end because that process could have, I'm not saying that it necessarily has but it could have created more wealth. Which would then create more demand, therefore other things that which would then create more jobs and more income and so on. Now of course, in reality the trickle down has not happened. Many governments do lots of things to basically, A: reduce the number of losers from the process of globalization and B: compensate the losers through public means. The one thing that has been prominently going on has been protection of agricultural in some of the rich countries. In countries like Japan, Norway, Switzerland, they have this agricultural sector, which is by international standard, very unproductive. But they deliberately keep these people in the agricultural sector partly to maintain their tradition, partly to prevent depopulation of the rural areas but also in recognition of the fact that if exposed to the market forces, these people would just disappear and they won't be able to convert themselves into investment banking or IT engineering. The U.S has provided huge amount of protection and subsidies to the steel industry, while pretending that the practice is free trade because the steel industry is too large and politically too important just to be left to go bankrupt. Of course, all these measures are costly, in the end a lot of things are wound down but a lot of countries are doing things in recognition that you will have a lot of people that are thrown into the scrapbook of history if you just let this global market forces reign. Governments can do something more proactive but to help people to find new jobs and the Scandinavian countries have been particularity good at this, they call this active labor market policy. Which means, instead of just saying that, yeah you have lost your job but you should find another job, they provide subsidized training, they try to help people look for jobs. Very often the problem is that when you lose your job in a town that used to make ships and somehow get retrained and try to move to another town to work as a software engineer, you often have to sell your house to buy another one and then the finances become very tricky. So the government in Sweden has even given temporary loans to these people to be able to buy a new house and pay them back when they sell their original house. So you can do these range of things to improve labor mobility. So when you have winners from some economic process whether it's trade liberalization or technological progress, the government can collect more taxes from them because they now have a higher income and use that to compensate the losers by providing them with income support, unemployment benefit, subsidized training, access to basic services. And maybe this can help out a lot of people, maybe still fall behind but not so dramatically as their counterparts in countries with smaller welfare state would do, if you're talking about the rough size of the welfare state. In Western Europe it's typically around the 25% of GDP, many countries help out 30%, France, Finland, Belgium. In the U.S. it's about 20%, in South Korea it's 10%. In countries like Korea and the U.S., the income support, unemployment benefit is minuscule, a lot of other people have a very tough life once they lose their jobs. Because the factor mobility, especially labor mobilities are rather low, the market mechanism can not fully compensate the losers and the governments have had to intervene a lot through various means, welfare state, labor market, trade protection, in order to minimize the negative consequences from this. Given this problem of insufficient compensation you'd ask whether as a neoclassical economist who believe in Pareto criterion, you should endorse all this process. A lot of neoclassical economists have advocated globalization fully knowing that it will create a lot of losers on the ground that the aggregate gains of the winners is going to be bigger than the aggregate loses of the losers. Therefore, in theory you can compensate all the losers and the winners will still have left something behind. This is known as the compensation principle in neoclassical welfare economics but if you believe in that you would have to make sure that this compensation is made. If it is not made, the neoclassical economist are doing the same thing as the people they use to condemn like the utilitarian philosophers or the Marx's economist who demanded sacrifice of a minority for the greater good. What they are saying is, liberalized trade, some people get left behind, is still okay because the aggregate wealth is greater. That's not Pareto. That's completely against Pareto principle. I mean what's the difference between that and Stalin? Who said what? We can kill a few million people in order to make the great nation better off. So this is seriously that, philosophical and ethical with the Christian here. In the absence of full trickle down, in the absence of full compensation, the result of bad globalization has been broadly increasing inequality. It hasn't happened in all countries but in over 2/3 rds of the countries, inequality has risen since the 1980's and in some countries, in a very dramatic way. Globalization has been going on for at least two centuries, some people say five centuries but I'm talking about the last 30, 40 years. The problem is that the current phase of globalization is that it has failed to produce accelerated growth because when this pro-market, pro-liberalization policies commonly known as neoliberal policies, came into stream in the 1980's it was very much predicated on that argument. Gross is that the fortunate entrepreneur measures being choked by government regulation. We need to revive the economy, open it up, deregulate, increase competition, that is drive people to become more productive. but when you look at the evidence that is not what has happened. Now before actually looking at the evidence let me make one point, we very often hear that, thanks to globalization we are richer than ever. In itself, it doesn't really mean anything because we will be richer than ever as per our economy is growing faster than population. So the relevant question is whether we are doing better than what we use to and the evidence tells you, that isn't the case. Roughly speaking, for a few decades after the Second World War, the world economy was growing very healthily, 2.6%. In the next 35 years, gross has markedly slowed down, basically it has been halved down to 1.4%. So we might be richer than ever but these numbers tell you that we could have been even richer, if we had maintained the previous raise of growth, we would be even richer. Most countries in this Ohlin period were actually using rather interventionist policies and they had a lot more restrictions on internationalization of the economy. Globalization was a very controlled affair in those days. All though there was a gradual globalization, even the rich countries had capital control, they had tariffs, all kinds of trade restrictions on foreign direct investment. So that makes you think, I mean, how come you had this sort of period where most countries were using "bad policies" and the world economy grow much faster than what they have been in the last three and a half decades? When lots of things have been liberalized, opened up and so on. Now when you say this, some people say, oh yes, but you have to put this into context. At least the last three or four decades of globalization has lifted a huge number of people out of poverty. Especially in developing countries like China and India. In worldwide terms, that the working class people who have been hit very hard by the globalization process in the rich countries, yeah they probably belong to the top 10, 20% of the world income distribution. So some people have accused these people of being really spoiled. I mean you belong to a top 10, 20% of the world and you want to introduce all this restrictions in international trade and investment, which would make it more difficult for people down the ladder, like poor Chinese people whose trying to pull themselves out of poverty so that you can maintain some kind of relative position in your own economy. Now there's some truth in that argument but I think the argument has quite a number of serious problems. First of all, it is not just the working class people in the rich countries that have been left behind, a lot of our people in developing countries have also been left behind. So if you look at, especially regions like Latin America and Sub- Saharan Africa, where is the most diligently implemented neoliberal policies under pressure from the International Management Fund and the World Bank, which basically put all of the conditions on their loans, they're growth in the "Brave New World" has collapsed. If you go to Latin America, a lot of people complain about the bad old days of (mumbling speech). Per capita income in the region use to grow at over 3% per year in that period and in the subsequent 30 years, the growth rate is not even 1% per year. Sub-Saharan Africa was even worse, even in the 60's and 70's it was growing at 1.6% in per capita per year. Yeah, not super rate but it's not something to be scoffed at because this is essentially the rate that today's rich countries grew during their industry revolution. It looks bad only because you are comparing it to a rate in Korea or Taiwan with five, 6% per year but in the next 30 years the annual average was 0.2%. This means that after 30 years Sub-Saharan Africa's per capita income was only 6% higher than what it was 30 years ago. In a good year, China grows that much in six months. Now given that the rich countries during this period grew between 1.5 and 2% per year, this means that Latin American and Sub-Saharan Africa have been left behind. The gap between them and the rich countries have vastly widened. And unbeknownst to the outside world, China experiences literally hundreds of thousands of industrial strikes, local riots, demonstrations. You could go to these Chinese people and say, oh you should still be happy because you have become richer and Brazil has much worse income distribution than you, it doesn't work, because inequality matters only because you think you belong to a certain group. If I told you that there are 55 planets in the universe, which has intelligent beings and all of them are vastly richer than Earth, would you care? I wouldn't, I can't even go there. Probably some of the delicacies that these beings eat are toxic to me. This is not to devalue the kind of material progress that China has achieved in the last decades. It's been truly impressive but don't think that this makes all the Chinese people happy, there are lots of angry people there. Now having said that, I think we need to be positive and realize that it is possible to minimize the number of losers from this process and actually compensate them more generously, and indeed, all other countries have done this. So if you look at income inequality statistics you'll realize that despite having a much more open economy than the United States, the Netherlands and Canada have seen no negative change in income inequality in the last few decades. Income inequality is raising a little bit in Germany, Japan and Italy but only marginally. In Switzerland there's even evidence that at least in the 1990's income inequality fell. Now these are interesting facts because we have been told that these forces of globalization can not be stopped. Everyone has to just accept that. We have been told that these forces shouldn't be stopped because it's driven by a technological progress and therefore trying to meddle with them is like trying to turn the clock back. No, that's not true. A lot of countries have done things to contain the effects and despite having one of the least open economies in the rich world, the U.S. has experienced huge increase in inequality from what already was one of the highest levels among the rich world, exactly because it used different policies. There's the smaller welfare state, it's at the corporate governance system is much more pro-corporate, labor law is more anti-labor. So the typical reaction from the angry people in the U.S. was it's all because of the Chinese, it's all because factories moving to Mexico but the real reason for increase in inequality and the mass production of angry people in the U.S. lye actually elsewhere. It was other countries that have shown that despite being far more open to international economic forces they could contain inequality. There is another interesting historical fact that corroborates this point, in the late 19th century and early 20th century, roughly between 1870 and 1914 there was another high point of globalization. Roughly speaking, during this period the world economy was basically as globalized as it is today. In some ways it was more globalized, in some ways less. What were the technologies that they used to achieve that degree of globalization? Basically steamships and wired, not even wireless telegraph. In contrast, in the 1950's, 60's and 70's we had basically, all the technologies of communication and transportation that we have today except for the internet. In those days there were already airplanes, there were fax machines. Despite that, that period was much less globalized then the earlier period in the late 19, early 20th century, basically showing that technology is not a defining factor. The world economy was much less globalized in the early post Second World War period, compared to the late 19 early 20th century. Exactly because countries deliberately control the degree of globalization partly through national policies, partly through international agreements. So even today we shouldn't accept the outcomes of this globalization as a force of nature that we can avoid, a lot of countries have done lots of things to change the outcome. Once you begin to think that this is some irresistible force of nature then you basically lose control of your destiny.
Info
Channel: New Economic Thinking
Views: 127,788
Rating: undefined out of 5
Keywords: ha-joon chang, inet, institute for new economic thinking, economics, matthew kulvicki
Id: HVGJDwEWIrI
Channel Id: undefined
Length: 34min 24sec (2064 seconds)
Published: Tue Dec 10 2019
Related Videos
Note
Please note that this website is currently a work in progress! Lots of interesting data and statistics to come.