Slavery, Capitalism and the Making of the Modern World

Video Statistics and Information

Video
Captions Word Cloud
Reddit Comments
Captions
[MUSIC PLAYING] Thank you, everyone, for coming out this evening to tonight's event on "Slavery, Capitalism, and the Making of the Modern World." My name is Zach Sell. I'm a visiting research scholar at the Center for the Study of Slavery and Justice and also a visiting faculty fellow at the Center for the Study of Race and Ethnicity in America. And I'm really grateful for the opportunity to introduce and participate in tonight's Sawyer Seminar on "Slavery, Capitalism, and the Making of the Modern World" co-sponsored by the Watson Institute, the Initiative on Race and Indigeneity, the Center for Latin American and Caribbean Studies, and the Center for the Study of Slavery and Justice. As a visitor at CSSJ, I can say that events like this are really essential to the work that the center does and its dedication to investigating the history of slavery and its legacy. So tonight's seminar with Jennifer Morgan, Seth Rockman, Anthony Bogues, and Walter Johnson, I think features scholars who have, together, in different ways, fundamentally transformed the way that the relationship between slavery and capitalism is considered and understood, moving our understanding away from a debate about whether and to what extent slavery is a part of capitalism and toward a demand for understanding how racial slavery structured capitalism. I think this shift has also enabled, really, a deeper understanding of the continuing presence of slavery's imprint upon post-slavery capitalism. So I think to appreciate just how firmly embedded the idea of a debate about slavery and capitalism is, one could look at the long shelves of books dedicated to the subject that have been published, really, since the 19th century. But I think rather than drag everyone again through the twists and turns and contours of that debate, I wanted to instead just note one minor moment in 1955 that I think is a moment that really also enables greater appreciation of the significance of seminars like the one we're having tonight. So this moment is preserved, actually, in the papers of WEB Du Bois In a short letter, Du Bois wrote to Eugene Genovese about the latter's master's thesis, plantation slavery, its unprofitability, and its relationship to capitalism. Du Bois noted that he hardly had time to offer any criticism of the work because he was busy. But even as such, he could see the absence of any consideration of the internal slave trade centrality in US capitalism and also noticed that Genovese did not engage in any serious way with Marxist writing. The implication of the Du Bois' response was that both historically and conceptually, Genovese's approach was offering very little. So if a person didn't know better, one might assume Genovese ultimately didn't receive the letter. He would go on to become perhaps the leading voice in 20th century discussions over the non-capitalist nature of US slavery and really disregarded this advice. And I think, from one perspective, this is really perhaps an unremarkable moment in that so-called "debate" about slavery and capitalism. But from another perspective, I think there's something in and within that ignorance that can able better appreciation of events like tonight's seminar. While Genovese's work enabled a long line of historians to create and debate a question, Du Bois' writing demanded a different mode of critiquing capitalism through understanding of slavery and its history and black emancipation in the US. Particularly in Black Reconstruction, Du Bois demanded a rethinking of concepts and history grounded in the realities of slavery which forced also a critical insight about the present. And I think it's that latter engagement rather than the former that makes seminars like tonight so important. And I think in very different ways, all of our panelists are working in critical relation to that latter tradition. And so I'm going to just very briefly introduce all of the panelists at once so we can get right into both presentations and conversation. And basically, the structure of tonight's events is, I think, everyone will present for about 15 minutes. And then we'll have a bit of a conversation between the panelists and then open up the room to broader conversation. So Jennifer Morgan is professor of history in the Department of Social and Cultural Analysis at New York University where she also serves as chair. She's the author of Laboring Women-- Gender and Reproduction in the Making of New World Slavery, and her most recent published work includes Accounting for "The Most Excruciating Torment--" Trans-Atlantic Passages. She is currently at work on a project that considers colonial numeracy, racism, and the rise of the transatlantic slave trade in the 17th century English Atlantic world. Seth Rockman is associate professor of history here at Brown. His 2009 book Scraping By-- Wage Labor, Slavery, and Survival in Early Baltimore received multiple prizes, including the Philip Taft Labor History Book Award. He's most recently published Negro Cloth-- Mastering the Market for Slave Clothing in Antebellum America, which was in the edited volume, American Capitalism. And Seth and Sven Beckert have recently also co-edited Slavery's Capitalism-- A New History of American Economic Development. Tony Bogues. Probably most people in the room have taken his classes and know him in some way. But he's director of the Center for the Study of Slavery and Justice. He's author of Caliban's Freedom-- The Early Political Thought of CRL James, Black Heretics and Black Prophets, and he's also the editor of several volumes including After Man Towards the Human-- Critical Essays on Sylvia Wynter. And right now, he is a visiting research fellow at the International Institute of Social History in Amsterdam. And last, Walter Johnson is Winthrop Professor of History at Harvard and author of Soul by Soul-- Life Inside the Antebellum Slave Market and also A River Of Dark Dreams-- Slavery and Empire in the Mississippi Valley's Cotton Kingdom. He's currently writing A History of the City of St. Louis-- From Lewis and Clark to Michael Brown. Johnson is also a founding member of the Commonwealth Project which joins academics and activists in an effort to create a community-controlled art space in the third ward of St. Louis. And so I think with that, we'll begin with Jennifer, if I'm not mistaken. Are you guys going to use the podium? I am, because I'm going to put some images up. Whatever you want. I think I'm going to go ahead and just stay seated, if that's OK with everybody. Is that all right? OK. So first of all, thank you for the invitation to be part of this conversation. I'm going to just talk through some ideas that I have. And I really look forward to unpacking them together with my fellow panelists. So at the risk of oversimplifying, I want to start by saying that race and racism make us lazy thinkers. They stand in for careful consideration of processes and offer up simple explanations for complex and foundational historic phenomenon. We live in a moment when we simply cannot fathom an encounter between an African and European-descended person unsaturated by racial recognition or racial hierarchy. The longstanding work of scholars to explain or to understand the development of transatlantic slavery seems forever constricted by the terms of the discussion-- which, again, forgive me for the oversimplification-- was the trade in slaves economically rational, or was it racist? We fail to see the ways in which both economic rationality and racial hierarchy come into sharp relief at the same time, that the two processes are interwoven, and that as a result, the way that the question has long been framed leaves crucial aspects not just unanswered but unasked. The afterlife of slavery has saturated not just our imaginations but indeed our disciplines and our methodological stance in relationship to the archive. I'm thinking, for example, of something I recently encountered that straddles the relationship between slavery, political economy, and culture in a way that I found illuminating. "When the Portuguese first arrived in Western Africa in the 15th century both on Cape Verde and then onto the coast, their desire for trade was facilitated by alliances between them and local traders, often alliances that were cemented through marriage. Such relationships and the children born of them have mostly been understood by African historians as evidence that stands in the way of a European propensity for racialist thinking. And therefore, by extension, it stands as evidence that the Portuguese didn't rush into their future as slave traders. We find it difficult-- or at least, I find it difficult-- to see the intimacy of marriage between a European man and an African woman on the coast of West Africa as not--" I think there are too many negatives in this sentence-- "but as not functioning as a bulwark against the trade in slaves. We fail to register or to fully explore, to work out, how to articulate the ways in which the economic dimensions of what would become hereditary racial slavery produced ways of thinking that make economies and polities on the West African coast difficult to understand as such." In other words, the example of those marriages gets put on the side of culture, the production of culture or the production of ideas about race, rather than seeing those things as embedded in these early economic formations and as evidence of political economy at work as well as polities at work. Somehow, we also fail to see how women on the coast, whose vulnerability to capture and transport began to encroach on a previous possibility of strategic and possibly affective alliances, could be the route through which we as scholars can see a process unfolding as they did, a way that we can see the intimacies of race, trade, and what would become hereditary racial slavery. Even when we emphasize the long duration of the transatlantic slave trade, the 400 years, we end up inadvertently turning it into a single episode in time. The particulars of the trade are flattened even as we attempt to convey the impact of its long duration. This idea that this is, again, an example of the way that race, I think, makes us lazy thinkers. And it's related to the concern that Vince Brown has expressed regarding the notion of "the condition of slavery," that the term "condition," the "condition" of being enslaved, the "condition" of slavery, inadvertently produces stasis. In its place, he offers us the phrase the "predicament of enslavement." How do we understand the predicament of enslavement? My strong conviction is that by breaking down the period of Atlantic slavery into clearly understood and demarcated periods of time, we will be in a much better position to understand its predicaments. And by doing so in the early modern period, as I am gesturing towards here-- oh, excuse me-- in a very short-handed way-- That was a hell of a gesture. That was quite a gesture-- gesturing towards here. By doing so, the particularities of those predicaments will shed crucial light on what has fundamentally been a quite successful project of naturalizing both the connection between slavery and race and obfuscating the connection between slavery and capitalism. We have so fully inherited the narratives of slavery and the slave trade crafted for us by 18th century abolitionists that I think that we sometimes don't always understand the ways in which slavery and the slave trade were deeply embedded in the emergence of late medieval and early modern notions of trade, a value of exchange, of currency, and ultimately, of the relationship between population, the accumulation of wealth, and the nation state-- all of which comprise early modern capitalism and capitalist formations. So I've been working in the late 15th and 16th century these days, trying to think through the European and West African turn to the Atlantic. As vistas to the east expanded, I think a range of material and ideological technologies came into play for rulers, for merchants, for ideologues, and for travelers in both Europe and West Africa. Numeracy, which is my way of capturing a whole range of ideas about rationality, about numbers, about trade, about currency, about attention to demography, all of these were just some of the new modes of thinking that accompanied the origins of the modern Atlantic world. In England and on the West African coast, traders and scholars were reconsidering their understanding of wealth, of trade, and the ways in which states benefited from an idea of population. For English theorists, that "notion" of counting population is called political arithmetic. And it becomes demography and understanding demographic strengths and vulnerabilities. On the African coast, traders began to see populations as marketable in new and more fungible ways as slavery came to mean something entirely different. And by this, I mean African traders. I don't mean European traders who are on the coast. And as slavery came to mean something entirely different and was premised on an unspoken idea that population was somehow infinite, simultaneously, the language of race and racial hierarchy shifted longstanding concepts of who was different, who was foreign, who was an ally, who was an enemy, and emerged to shape the trade in slavery and the goods produced by slave labor and in the settler colonialism that would come to comprise the core means by which wealth was transferred across and around the Atlantic. So both numeracy and race thinking shaped and were shaped by the social and cultural processes that attended their use. Neither are fixed or static tools. But together, they forged rationalized meaning through the interplay between the supposed logic of calculus and the alchemy of race making. And this is all a lot of shorthand, which I'm happy to talk about a little bit more. Historians have long agreed that the economic transformations of the late 16th and the early 17th century were accompanied by new symbolic meanings that far exceeded the economy. But somehow that understanding stops inside of Europe and doesn't include slavery. Our most foundational theorists of early histories of capitalism-- I'm thinking about Braudel, for example, who, as he introduces the concept of the labor market says, in a kind of parentheses, he says, that he, as Marx did, quote, "will leave aside the classic case of slavery, which was however to be prolonged and even renewed." And this gesture of saying like, yes, slavery, but I'm not going to talk about it because I'm talking about Europe, is really the groundwork on which many revisionists stand. So new ways of thinking were the norm in 17th century England, which is where I'm working right now. And contemporary observers understood that significant shifts were underway regarding the role of merchants and traders and producing the wealth of monarchies and states. They were careful and deciduous in trying to explain these new ways of thinking. 17th century English policy around trade and commerce reflected a crucial moment in the development of Atlantic markets. And it was at this moment that foundational commitments to an empire rooted in colonial commodities markets and dependent on slave labor took hold. So we see that, and we understand that if we're reading the history of political economy. But what we don't ever do, or what we rarely do, is think about the experience of those people who are being transformed into commodities in this early period not in the 18th century and the 19th century but right at the time when it's beginning under the hands of the Portuguese and the Spanish and then ultimately other European nations. And we don't turn that gaze back to think about how they are also producing, in some ways, theories of early commodification and of early capitalism. And so that effort to try to read the archive back on this process is at the heart of what I'm involved in. So how long have I been talking? You have just a few more minutes. OK, I'm very close. OK, so I think that we need to ask questions about the way that hereditary racial slavery emerges at a moment in which all sorts of questions about population, about currency, and about trade and about value are circulating. They're circulating out of Europe. They're circulating on the West African coast, and they are being transformed. The questions that I'm asking are clearly related to and in dialogue with the newly invigorated scholarship on capitalism and slavery that has followed Eric Williams foundational work and that is exemplified by the crucial work of my fellow panelists. I think though that I'm asking a slightly different set of questions, as I come to this not from the perspective of a scholar of capital but rather as a scholar of gendered power and of racialized intimacy. It's this location that shapes my interest less in the structural relationship between slavery and capitalism and more with emergent cultural practices in which the fungibility of humans and the growth of early modern slave societies is rendered logical. Because it's in that logic-- it is that logic-- that hides the subjects that I'm most interested in understanding. And therefore, as I grapple with the archive that's available to me, it's the process of rendering questions unanswerable that is most crucial to my work. And so for me, what is the most important thing about the intersection between slavery and capitalism in the early modern period is the way that it transforms certain subjects into marginalia. So the subjects that-- and by subjects, I mean intellectual subjects, but also the people-- so that those women whose bodies are producing hereditary racial slavery and whose bodies are the sight of law and theory and new power relations are then erased from our archive in ways that everybody in this room is intimately familiar with but that are ways that we still really need to continue to focus on. So I will stop there. Thank you. [APPLAUSE] I'm going to stand because I'm going to show a couple of images here. So it might take a minute to put down the screen. While that's happening, let me just say there are a couple of chairs. There's one here. There's one here, if people are looking. Yes, all right, how about that? All right, great, there's some chairs here. There's a chair here for those who are standing who'd like to sit down. You're welcome to do so. There are not a lot of them, and I'm sorry to my fellow panelists for sticking you with this. What a treat to be here. Thank you all for coming out tonight. To be on a panel with some of my favorite scholars is really something that's quite special. One of the things that I like so much about the conversation that's emerged about the relationship of slavery and capitalism is that it's taking place on so many different scales. It can be done on massive macroeconomic terms, looking at processes of growth and development over hundreds of years, looking at data sets that run centuries. It can be done by looking at very small technologies, things like the account book for instance. It can be done by zooming in on particular places, connecting the global and the local. And the work that I've been trying to do is trying to take this, perhaps, to some of the most quotidian and small spaces possible. And from a very, very precise location, expand and imagine outward the ways in which slavery and capitalism are connected to one another in the decades between the American Revolution and the Civil War. So the place that I want to start is with a list. So when Mary Rodman sat down to sew frocks in 1840, she consulted this list of dimensions. The first frock was for someone who stood 4' 11" and measured 38 inches around the waist. The next frock would have to be longer, about 56 inches from collar to hem, in order to fit a woman 5 foot, 6 inches tall. As she worked down the list, number four, number five, and so forth, Rodman might have contemplated the dollar she earned for every six frocks. She had to remember to attach a tag with these dimensions legibly ascribed to each frock so they would get to the intended recipient. At 5' 11", number three on her list was very tall for the time. Number 10 must have been a child at only 4' 3". The inhabitants of these measured bodies might not have warranted a second thought for Rodman, who soon turned to another order involving not just frocks but also shifts, the cotton undergarments worn closest to a woman's skin. Likely wearing a near identical garment under her own dress, the 13-year-old Rodman perhaps did not pause to think about number five, number six, or number seven. But this kind of sewing was tedious. And so why shouldn't Rodman's mind wander from South Kingston, Rhode Island, to the wearers of her handiwork, someplace far away? Now, New England girls like Rodman and their mothers had taken in sewing for generations whether as parts of networks of neighborly exchange that structured rural communities or thanks to more recent practices of merchants, storekeepers, and manufacturers distributing cut cloth to local families to stitch in exchange for store credits. Outwork, as it was called, had proven a particularly effective means of mobilizing the labor of wives and daughters in the countryside, and it contributed significantly to Rhode Island's industrial output. The proprietors of a local carding mill would have furnished Mary's grandmother with wool roving to spin into yarn under her own wheel. And once spinning mills began producing vast quantities of yarn, Mary's mother would have accepted warp and filling to weave on a family loom. And now that weaving had been mechanized, Mary received pre-cut cloth to assemble into garments at home. Skeins of yarn, pieces of cloth, stacks of trousers were returned to the hands of the merchant or manufacturer who had furnished the initial supplies. And even at low rates, this outwork provided supplemental income to families like the Rodmans, who, particularly because they were paid in store goods, gained or maintained access to the teapots, the ribbons, and the other consumer goods that had defined middle class respectability in the New England countryside. Take a step back. The expansive trade networks of the early modern world had long embedded the local experience of work within global systems of supply and distribution. The 19th century New England women who turned Argentine wool into textiles for Louisiana slaves followed in the footsteps of the Gujarat weavers, the [? Guanzou ?] porcelain decorators, and the countless other pre-industrial workers who transformed raw materials they themselves did not produce into export commodities they themselves did not use. The entangled relationship of remote producers and consumers has been a defining characteristic of modern world history, as has the ease and speed with which these connections have become routinized, and by extension, invisible. If a New Hampshire farm girl in the '30s ever stopped in the middle of weaving or in the middle of braiding Caribbean palm leaves into hats for Mississippi boatmen and thought to herself-- this is weird. I'm in New Hampshire-- palm leaves from Cuba to go on the heads of men in Mississippi, right? She left no record of such musings, for posterity. More likely, her own experience as a consumer of buttons and raisins and other commonplace imports had so naturalized commercial interconnections as to make them unworthy of comment. School texts, for instance, the kind of school books that Mary Rodman might have looked at, like Emma Willard's Geography for Beginners, reinforced the point, reminding her that the entire world could be found on the shelves of the country store, where she earned credits for the shifts and frocks that she sewed. Now, lurking behind this world of goods, then as now, were relations of power that structured work, the questions of who did it, on what terms, and to whose benefit. Equally in the shadows were the ideological, theological, and ethical commitments that made these patterns of production and exchange business as usual-- the unarticulated and unquestioned assumptions that said it was perfectly appropriate for a 13-year-old girl to sew frocks for money, or that might have prompted that girl, Mary Rodman, to think long and hard, or to think not at all, about the frocks that she was sewing. Various disruptions, of course, the hurricane that destroyed the crop, the machine that made the traditional form of labor redundant, the financial panic that obliterated commercial credit-- all of these could readily reconfigure patterns of global integration. And they do so into locally experienced forms of insecurity, to bring people face to face with truths long unstated. Taxation and military occupation, for example, had forced colonists like Mary Rodman's great-grandparents to confront their affection with tea and textiles as well as to assess the value of their relationship to the British Empire. Moral revolutions could also call the questions when Quaker communities at the heart of transatlantic commerce began to testify against African slavery. By the end of the 18th century, a number of Anglo-American merchants and manufacturers had concluded that trading in human beings was illegitimate commerce and that producing shackles was an immoral use of a forge. Their compatriots insisted that consumers in England and North America grapple with the remote exploitation that sweetened their tea and their cakes. The agitation leading to the abolition of the Atlantic slave trade is emblematic of how long standing relationships of production and consumption can suddenly become a problem. And scholars have lavished attention on the reformulation of capitalism in this changed environment. It was here, for instance, that political economists, moral reformers, and businessmen alike imagined a liberal economy predicated on the competitive striving of the self-owned and the self-made. Several decades on the other side of that reckoning, Mary Rodman was born into a Rhode Island where slave-grown cotton was a crucial ingredient in the state's economy and where numerous families spun, wove, and sewed for plantation markets. This relationship would not attain the status of a problem for most [? doing ?] lenders. Commercial entanglements occasionally garnered a comment from organized abolitionists in the 1830s and 1840s but rarely prompted a call to close the textile mills on account of their complicity in slavery several states away. Nor could one hear public defamations of girls like Mary Rodman whose sewing was in the service of a Mississippi plantation 1,500 miles away. Although Rhode Island outworkers often assembled parcels of clothing in assorted sizes, Rodman was tasked with filling a very specific order-- for James A. Ventress, a European-educated cotton planter who would soon serve as a founding trustee of the University of Mississippi. But her neighbors did likewise. Harry Stedman's wife produced 29 frocks for the enslaved women owned by the notorious slave trader Isaac Franklin. Sally Gardner stitched 52 frocks and shifts for the women whom William Stamp held in captive in Fort Adams, Mississippi. These Rhode Island girls and women manufactured within a system whose larger workings had once again retreated into the background, ostensibly requiring no comment or second thought as they bound producers and consumers across space. Nor did it matter to Mary Rodman's work life that the skills she brought to her sewing, the pride that she took in her work, the social status or stigma that such labor brought to her, the subjectivity that she developed as a worker, that she made frocks and shifts for enslaved women as opposed to some other item, some other commodity, some other connection to New England's industrial transformation. At first glance, the answer is no. The basic contours were the same as for the vast majority of New England girls and women who navigated industrialization over the first decades of the 19th century. Outwork offered rural families the opportunity to deploy female labor more directly towards the acquisition of a higher material standard of living while the concurrent rise of mechanization in factory wages tempered those opportunities by more explicitly transforming labor into a commodity and subjecting it to intensifying regimes of discipline. Mary Rodman saw this firsthand, moving from sewing at home as a teenager to toiling in a factory within just a few years. Whether brooms for urban housekeepers, butter for city grocers, straw bonnets for fashionable ladies, shoes for whalemen, or shifts for slaves, the story was largely the same. And yet I think it would be an error to presume that laboring New Englanders did not confront the distinct moral and political implications of their work on behalf of the slave system. By the 1830s, the public discussion of slavery and its abolition were already loud enough to require people to pick sides, or to make excuses, or to engage in willful obliviousness. At the same time, a racist popular culture provided a predictable store of stereotypes to white residents of the North for denigrating the black men and women who would wear the clothing they stitched or the hoes they forged or the shoes they pegged. In other words, Mary Rodman did not sew in a vacuum, but rather she did so in the midst of particular political and cultural contests over the boundaries of slavery and freedom. And in communities like hers in South Kingston, the legacies of slave holding, of gradual emancipation, of colonialism, further shaped the contours of earning one's living weaving Negro cloth or pegging slave brogans. If nothing else, it would require the New England makers of plantation goods, as this collective body of northern manufacturers was called, to undertake additional work-- social, spiritual, cultural-- to contend that their labor had no further moral political implications, that it bore no reflection of their own ethical standing, or that their handiwork carried no additional signification-- that sometimes a shovel was just a shovel. The risk was not merely the opprobrium of sanctimonious reformers. It could also be the ribbing that one would get in the tavern for making a living by making hoes for slaves. At the same time, what were the possibilities for a Rhode Island woman like Dorcas Babcock, sewing clothing for Mississippi slaves, perhaps envisioning herself in the guise of her biblical namesake, toiling with devotion to cover the naked and to comfort the suffering? So all in all, these possibilities raised questions of how these economies are connected to one another generally. But more specifically-- and to take a term that has been very much in the conversation, complicity-- to think about how complicity is lived, to create a project in which not asking or searching for the smoking gun to prove that the North had an interest in slavery, or that Rhode Island women made livelihoods for themselves fashioning clothing for slaves. To take this as a given, but then to ask questions about how it was lived, how it was experienced in the 19th century, and to ask what difference this would make to other historical developments-- the entrepreneurial culture, for instance, that made New England the Silicon Valley of the 1820s, or the plantation politics in which enslaved people contested the authority of their legal owners and sought to mitigate the worst aspects of their bondage by arguing over such things as these provisions. So by following plantation goods from the communities in which they were made into those in which they were used, one sees not merely complicity but contingency. That is the unpredictable ways in which choices made in one place have reverberations and shape what choices are possible in another. The unintended consequences of the best laid plans, the entanglements of remote lives that are bound together by something so mundane as a frock or a shift. It is here I suggest that historians find the most surprises in the past. And so what I've spoken to you about tonight is ultimately out of a book that I'm now finishing that is about these relationships tying remote producers and consumers to one another through these very mundane artifacts like shoes and hats and hoes and boots and other textiles that put Yankee ingenuity in the service of the slave plantation. I study the New England entrepreneurs who mobilized this market. I study laborers like Mary Rodman who produced these goods. I consider the middlemen and merchants who organized the trade, the slave holders who constructed their own notions of mastery on the distribution of these goods, and of course, the enslaved people who incorporated these goods into their work lives and into their strategies of survival. These stories blur some of the boundaries of the geography of slavery. And recovering these relationships is vital to rethinking this geography in the 18th and 19th century when, what some scholars have called the hinterlands of the slave economies, places far removed from the plantation zones themselves, nonetheless provided crucial material support to a violent system of agricultural commodity production. And you can just think about some of the ways in which these connections work. And they're familiar to us and a modern sensibility where we're more attuned to being aware of these remote connections between producers and consumers across space. So enslaved men and women on a sugar plantation in [? San ?] [? Domingo ?] may have been purchased in West Africa with linens woven in Silesia, copper bars smelted in Wales, or rum distilled in Rhode Island. They may have been sustained on salt beef barreled in Ireland or dressed in textiles from the Lake District in Northwest England. They might have worked at night by the light of a spermaceti candles rolled in Nantucket. And to follow thee pathways of these goods is to raise questions about the investments of these remote communities of interest in the establishment and perpetuation of Atlantic slavery over several centuries. These increasingly far flung entanglements across geographical space and across distinct regimes of labor become visible across these global commodity chains leading to the production of any particular New England good. The kind of textiles that Mary Rodman was sewing likely contained wool that had come from Argentina or from Smyrna, meaning that the lives of a Mediterranean sheep rancher were somehow connected through these goods to the lives of a Mississippi field hand. We can play this out longer. That wool might have been cleaned by institutionalized poppers at the New York City alms house before being dyed red using cochineal from Mexico, woven on looms outfitted with reeds from South Carolina, finished at a filling mill using teasels imported from France. Where will you draw the line? Asked one antebellum critic of the slave system, where does slavery stop? And ultimately, this is where I will leave you tonight with this question, looking at these goods, and thinking about the ways in which these commodity chains tie people far from the plantation to the perpetuation of the slave system. We must ask ourselves about the geographical categories that have so long informed our study, looking at the boundaries between a so-called free North and a slave South, or a free labor economy and a slave labor economy, recognizing that these boundaries hardly sustain the kind of scrutiny that scholars can bring to these questions when they look at something so simple as a frock or a hat, a shift, a pair of shoes, or a hoe. Thank you so much. [APPLAUSE] Let's just wait till the screen goes up. I want to thank everybody for coming out. I particularly would like to thank Walter Johnson, Jennifer Morgan, and Seth Rockman for making this particular conversation possible and to Zach Sell for chairing. Also, I'd like to just send thanks of appreciation to the Center for Latin American Studies and their Sawyer Seminar series when they invited the center to participate. And to thank the center staff, both Maiyah Gamble-Rivers and Shana Weinberg, for organizing this. In the time allocated to me, I want to make a series of remarks drawn from a research project and a book that I'm now doing, tentatively titled Black Critique. The book is a fairly large book and began as a study of freedom. But I realized in writing it that I actually could not do a study of freedom without doing a study of the history of capitalism itself. And so I have about to put aside the sections of the text on freedom and turn to a study of the business of capitalism. Since 1944, Eric Williams' Capitalism and Slavery with a thesis that, essentially, colonial slavery was the foundation for the Industrial Revolution and for industrial capitalism, there has been a serious debate about capitalism and its relationship to slavery. I wanted to just put that debate in parentheses or put it in some kind of bracket, because I don't want to start with that debate. I actually want to start with a much earlier book, which is 1935 WEB Du Bois' Black Reconstruction. I would just want to submit that that is actually where the debate should begin. And I'm not quite sure why historians are beginning in 1944, and one has developed a whole thing on the Williams' thesis, when, in fact, the real thing about capitalism and slavery, or one of the most remarkable texts about capitalism and slavery, emerges in 1935, Du Bois' Black Reconstruction. Think of the beginning of the book of Black Reconstruction. Think of the chapter "The Black Worker," which essentially changes immediately the category of the enslaved to that of labor. And think of, therefore, what that means theoretically with the transformation of the category of the enslaved to that of worker and how that troubles a whole set of other ways in which we think about slavery. I would argue that Du Bois' book essentially repositioned slavery as central to America's economic development, to capitalism. Think again of the epigraph in chapter one where he makes it very clear that the arrival of the black man, he says-- and here I'm paraphrasing him-- to the United States is that he has always been a central part of the economic life of America and its democracy. I think that what Du Bois is trying to point that he is trying to make is that capitalism as a mode of production was not separate from racial slavery, that there were not two distinct racial systems, two distinct social systems, but that they were interconnected and that American slavery as could not be called a mode of production, of slave production, separate from capitalism. Now, the mode of production argument again appears in the 1970s with world systems theory, particularly in places like Brazil and in other parts of Latin America. There are a lot of work around Brazil as a slave mode of production, particularly in the 1980s looking at large agricultural lands as well as looking at the mining processes in Brazil. There is also a vast literature in Latin America which does not talk about slave mode of production but talks about the colonial mode of production in Latin America. So in other words, there has been a preoccupation not just with the questions of slavery and its relationship to capitalism, but there has been a preoccupation as, how do you identify slavery itself? What can you call slavery? How can you call slavery as a labor process and as an economic process, not just as a social system? What is the relationship between colonialism and slavery? What I want to suggest that Du Bois did was to shift the gears from arguments about mode of production or any descriptive argument about what capitalism is that is primarily a system of wage worker en masse within a factory system but focuses on labor in a different kind of way. I would want to remind you as well that when Du Bois was doing Black Reconstruction in 1935 that prior to that, in 1933, that he was given classes at Atlanta University on capital, which means that he was reading Marx and then trying to through Marx and his relationship to America. My remarks, therefore, begins with that Du Boisian perspective of labor and slave labor and its relationship to capitalism. A great deal of historical work over the past decade or so has been done about what is now called the history of capitalism. Good old Cambridge University and Cambridge University Press has published in 2014 a two-volume history. There has been remarkable scholarship produced by members on this panel, Seth, Walter, and Jennifer. There have been many others who are not in this room who have really tried to think about the relationship between capitalism and history. In this particular pattern or trajectory of scholarship, certain categories have emerged. One category is what is called war capitalism. Another category that was there long before, in particular in the work of Cedric Robinson from 1983, is what has been called racial capitalism. In Europe, Marcel van der Linden has developed a notion of plantation capitalism as a way to begin to think about a different global history of labor. In all of these works, I would want to suggest there are some general features-- that of violence, the question of accumulation, the question of circulation, the ways in which economic institutions operate. And also in many of the works, there has been a focus on the 19th century. And of course, in all of the works, there has been a focus on racialized black bodies. What is also, I think, important in thinking about this body of literature is that in the discussions of the histories of capitalist capitalism, there have been a certain set of prefixes so that there is primitive accumulation, which then leads to merchant capitalism, which then merchant capitalism leads to industrial capitalism, which then leads to financial capitalism. And then which then leads us to late capitalism today and neoliberalism. So that there is a way in which a prefix is then used as a designator to describe what exactly capitalism is or what is the periodization of this particular system. I want to trouble that a bit, some of these prefixes and periodization. And I suggest that in thinking about race, slavery, and capitalism that we are in a new economic, social formation in which questions of that of capitalism, that of commodification, exploitation, alienation, and freedom itself now need to be rethought. One will not have time here for the full argument, but the argument I am making has enormous political consequences for struggles against various forms of domination as well as for historical analysis. Let me for a moment, for example, consider the conventional prefix merchant capital, which is sometimes-- which is not sometimes, which is oftentimes-- subtracted from financial. So merchant and then financial capitalism, of course, one can begin this particular critique by beginning to look at the work of Rosa Luxembourg and her major theoretical work, The Accumulation of Capital-- A Contribution to the Economic Explanation of Imperialism published in Berlin in 1913 in which she began to talk about enlarged position. But one of the problems of that particular work, as well as in many other works, is not just a question of what some of us call a commercialization thesis, but really, as a way in which capitalism is constructed as an abstract pure form, as a kind of ideal form in which the laws of society and the laws of motion of capital actually operate. My argument there, however, is that there is really no ideal form, even in any abstract and then abstractions. And that ideal forms and theoretical abstractions are, in fact, very brittle. And so that what I like to say is, if one is going to theorize a system, then one needs to begin to theorize that system from a set of historical experiences and to do what I call theory from history. So therefore, let us get a little bit historical and concrete, keeping in mind the business of the categories of merchant and finance. Let me go immediately to the Netherlands. And to accompany this is this firm called the VOC. The VOC is formed in 1602. The capital of the VOC is 6.5 million guilders at that particular point in time. It has 200 shareholders. It has a board of directors. It is a transnational company. I'm talking 1602. It is a transnational company. Its central offices in Amsterdam, it employs 350 persons. Its portfolio when you look at its books contains the following things-- slave trade, plantation investments both in the Caribbean as well as in Indonesia, investment in the spinning wheel in India, investments in South Africa. The laws and the regulations governing the VOC is that it can conduct war. It can conclude treaties. It can take possession of land, and it can build fortresses. Now, to me, what you're looking at, therefore, is not now just a trading company. What you're looking at is both a finance and a trading company. And its sister company, the West Indies Company, is essentially constructed very similarly. But it has a lot more heavy side to it with investment houses. And these investment houses are important because these are the investment houses that does two things. One, they do engage in the slave trade. And secondly, they give money to the planters, in Suriname particularly, in the Caribbean, to set up their plantations. And this is really very funny. I mean, I was reading some of their books and some of their account books. And what was interesting was not only do they give the money, the credit, to the planters to actually set up the plantations, but they actually buy the source of food for the slaves and the planters and then sell it to them at a profit. So it is really a total system, but it's a system actually based on a certain kind of investment. So what you really have are merchant bankers. And these merchant bankers who run these particular investment houses, therefore, in my view, complicate the idea that somehow this is really merchant capitalism, mercantile capitalism, and then financial capitalism later on in the 19th century. Well, what you really have, in my view, is actually dominance of finance. And how does one see this? There are 2,000 plantations in the small territory of Suriname. One of the very first collapse of the stock exchanges that we have in economic history is 1773 in Amsterdam. What's the problem? Why you have the stock exchange crash? You have this problem because the people have given, the investment houses have given, the planters in Suriname money for their plantations. The planters cannot pay it back. So there is a debt crisis. When one looks at the numbers, it's not really a serious debt crisis. But there is a panic that somehow this will be larger than what has been there before. And then this leads to a crash in 1773 in the Amsterdam stock exchange. So what is important as I'm saying to you is that here you are one of the first stock exchanges in the world, but at the foundation of that, which is a financial instrument, at the foundation of that is actually plantation, is racial slavery. Or you can take another company, if you want to leave the Dutch, and you go to the English. And take the English South Sea Company of 1720 in which Isaac Newton is an investor. And what is interesting is how that company again crashes. But it doesn't crash because people think that the people can't pay back debts but because there is a rumor that people would not be able to pay back their debt. And as Isaac Newton said, I can understand astronomy. I can understand the stars. But I cannot understand, as he says, the multitude's madness. And so therefore, what I would want to suggest is that what we have, therefore, is that the colonial enterprise is an enterprise of merchants and of bankers. And that of the slavery enterprise is the enterprise of merchants, bankers, and plantations, or of planters. To think about this a little bit deeper, one might want to then think about the plantation itself, since we're looking at racial slavery. And a lot of the ideas that we have of the plantation is that it is primarily agricultural. And I would want to suggest to you that that's not so, that in fact, the way in which a plantation was structured was really agro-industry. If you think of the Barbadian plantations, for example, and the production of sugar, if we think of the Brazilian plantations, if you think of even the production of Brazilian mines, mining in Brazil in the 1800s before the abolition of slavery, what you see is not just that people are doing sugar-- that is, cutting cane-- that they are actually sugar and that there is a process of making sugar. So there is an industrial process. And one of the fascinating things about this is that when you look at some of the work of the planters, they begin to call the particular plantations what they call a "perfect machine." And the idea, the language, of a perfect machine, therefore, is about trying to run a certain kind of industry. So what I would want to suggest, therefore, is that we might want to shift away from talking about a certain kind of capitalism as war capitalism, because in fact, colonial capitalism, if you want to call it that, it was about conquest and war. This is part of the way in which colonialism operates is about conquest. is about war, is about taking territory, et cetera. So that, therefore, that's what it unleashes. And that we might want to think about what I'm tentatively calling something called "slave capitalism," that is, a way in which, going back to prefixes, a way in which we can think through the question of labor, where we can think through the question of anti-black racism, the way in which we can think about what I'm calling the double commodification of labor. In other words, the ways in which the slave is not enslaved, is not just a person of labor power that produces something, but that is his or her body is also property, and therefore, that particular process of double commodification. And to then, therefore, think, what does that process of double commodification mean when we begin to think about not now those questions of exploitation but questions of alienation and questions of domination? So that while we need prefixes to try to help us analytically to come to grips with slavery and racial slavery, one of the things I would want to suggest is that in this business of trying to think through how the system actually works, one of the things that a very good theory said, in an unpublished manuscript, makes a point, Sylvia Wynter, is that what you're looking at is the reduction of man to labor and the reduction of nature to land, and what Raynal called in his 1770s book on the history of the Indies, "an odious commerce." And so therefore, to think about this particular reduction, to think about this processes of the double commodification, of the enslaved, means, in my view, that you now really have to think through a different conception of freedom, that no longer can you think about human emancipation as only circling around questions of [? which ?] label, but now you have to begin to think about the questions of human emancipation circling around this business of [? former ?] human domination. And therefore, it would just seem to me that one of the important questions of trying to think about a new history of capitalism is really also to think about a new history of what freedom might mean. Thanks. [APPLAUSE] I want to offer my thanks to the Center for the Study of Slavery and Justice, to Tony Bogues, to Zach Sell, and to Maiyah Rivers. Sell said that people were going to intervene in this question in different sorts of scales. And I thought that I was going to be at the largest scale until Tony said I'm writing a project on black critique, which was going to be a history of freedom. But then I realized I had to tackle the history of capitalism first. So this is going to seem [? really ?] [? puissant ?] in comparison. That was inspiring. I think something that runs through all the papers is the question of, where do our categories come from? And of trying to develop and to think through, to recognize, in the first instance, the extent to which the categories that we have used to understand the history of slavery and capitalism as two different things are, in fact, products of that history-- so to recognize the extent to which they're structured in dominance and to try to clean up, to decolonize, our methodology in different ways. And I think that is a project that as Tony in particular said is a project of long standing in what I would call the black radical tradition. And I'm going to start my way into that, which is through the work of Cedric Robinson. And then I'm also going to talk a bit about Du Bois. Black Marxism, for those of you who have not read it, it is a extremely complicated, very dense, and absolutely indispensable book. And one of the things that Robinson does in that book is that he establishes separate pathways. He establishes a pathway of history to describe the long history of bonded labor in Europe and its empire and the long history of xenophobia in Europe and its empire. And he's very, very concerned to try to treat those pathways as different to begin with. And what Robinson tries to illustrate through the course of Black Marxism or through the course of the first 250 pages, say, is that these are separate strands of history that become interwoven in the 15th century. But they're never identical to one another. And so when Tony talks about Du Bois' chapter "The Black Worker," what strikes me about that that title is that there's a tension there that Du Bois is creating. And I used to read it, and I used to think, oh, my god, Du Bois, he's become too Marxist. And he's overlaying the history of slavery with these Marxian categories about class, and he's making everybody seem like a worker, right? But that's not what he's doing. And it's only recently that I've understood the title of that chapter "The Black Worker" as being a chapter which has a dynamic tension in it. It's things which cannot be reduced to one another. So you can't simply argue that slavery was a class relationship because there's a libidinal character to white supremacy, to racial dominance, right? There's an excessive aspect to white supremacy and racial dominance that can't simply be understood through economic categories. So the example-- I mean, this is a different period, but the thing that I'm obsessed with currently is the history of St. Louis. And so in 1949, they opened the largest open air swimming pool in the world in the city of St. Louis. And on the opening day, three black kids jump in there. There's a riot in St. Louis. They close the pool, and they don't reopen it for the whole summer. Oh, my microphone. That's excessive, right? There's something about that that goes beyond some kind of notion of racism and white supremacy as a proxy for class relationships. But there are also-- and this has been harder for me to understand-- but there are also aspects of the history of racial capitalism that are so general, so hegemonic, that they are no longer in their dominant usage strictly racial. And it seems to me that this is, in a way, what Jennifer is talking about. It's the way that a set of technologies that emerge out of white supremacy and slavery become the technologies through which human beings as such are measured, the notion of population. And that's what I actually take away from Sylvia Wynter's notion of man, of the sort of universalization of a particular sort of person who is a historical product, the product of empire slavery and white supremacy but then becomes the way that people generally understand themselves now, so as a population or as people who think about their lives probabilistically or economically. And Wynter is, again, extremely difficult, somebody who I've only just started to read, but who hails us to try to find a different, deeper, and I think more loving notion of humanity. So if you take these ideas of these separate strands, these separate strands of commerce and xenophobia, the idea that's in Robinson is that these things are combined in slavery and settler colonialism and that that marks a new moment in the history of the world. The place that I would start with that in Du Bois is in 1926 in the essay on "The Souls of White Folk" in Darkwater. And what Du Bois argues in that essay is he argues that neither xenophobia nor bondage were new things in the 15th century. "Ever have men striven to conceive of their victims as different from the victors, endlessly different, in soul and blood, strength and cunning, race and lineage. Likewise, the using of man for the benefit of masters is in no way a new invention of modern Europe. It is quite as old as the world." So what he's saying there is that racial domination and economic exploitation each have very, very long histories. And [? then-- ?] "but Europe proposed to apply it on a scale and with an elaborateness of detail which no former world ever dreamed. The imperial width of the thing, its heaven-defying audacity makes its modern newness." So what Du Bois is saying there is that there's something new in world history about the slave trade. There's a new period in world history. And I would argue that that is the period of racial capitalism. Now, what I want to say about that is-- and it's going to be very, very gentle-- but it's not static or proleptic. And I think by proleptic, I mean I want to try to speak to something that I think Jennifer talked about at the beginning. Which is that it would be a mistake to take the idea of racial capitalism and imagine that what that means is that contemporary ideas of race have always existed. What the idea of racial capitalism seems to me to be about is about the dynamic co-creation and evolution, the dialectic of the notions of racial difference and capitalist practices. So it's a dynamic and contingent relationship that changes over time. So why do I think that this is a useful, important, crucial, essential idea? It seems to me that, first of all, the idea of racial capitalism treats the history of slavery, empire, and industrial development as simultaneous and integrated aspects of one another. It doesn't necessarily reduce them to one another. And so one of the critiques is going to be, well, if you say what happens in Manchester is capitalism and you say what happens in Mississippi is capitalism and you say what happens in Mali is capitalism, then how are we going to sort out the difference between Manchester, Mississippi, and Mali? That seems to me to actually be an infantile and fatuous and intentionally obstructionary reading. I mean, really? You know, honestly? We're not going to be able tell the difference between Manchester and Mississippi if somebody calls them both capitalist? It's ridiculous. OK, what I think this notion does is that it moves beyond-- and this is really to resonate with something that Tony said-- the notion of slavery as the prehistory of capitalism, as precapitalist. The term precapitalist, which has this enormous purchase in social science methodology, is actually an intellectually and historically incoherent term. It's teleological in an intellectually unsupportable way. And what it does then is it helps us think through, I think, the limitations of Marx, the limitations of Smith, the limitations of Braudel, all of whom treat slavery as a unfully-- thus, as Jennifer says-- pushed to the margins, prehistory of the main event, capitalism. The other thing-- and I want to insist on this, and I think it's important, and I think there's a conversation to be had here, Tony, about why one might want to insist on the notion of racial capitalism-- is it insists on the imperial aspect of racial capitalism. And in so doing, it draws attention in the history of the United States but also in the history of the Western hemisphere in general, to Indian removal and to genocide as integral aspects of the same process, right? So we all, in one way or another, are working out of an African-American intellectual tradition. But one of the things that I find powerful in Du Bois where there's an acknowledgment although not a, I think, substantial engagement with this question, is the idea of these things as imperial. And that imperial history, thus, then forcing us to think about, inviting us to think about, requiring that we think about, Native American dispossession as an aspect to this. That is, removal and genocide as well as labor exploitation and social reproduction generally are always already processes of sexual and reproductive domination, right? And this is, I think, again, to gesture, really, at Jennifer's first book. And so one of the things that I think the notion of racial capitalism then calls upon us to do is to think about the relationship of sexuality, reproduction, [INAUDIBLE] [? futurity ?] to empire and slavery. And how, then, when I try to talk about it, when I was talking earlier about thinking about racial capitalism as dynamic, one would want to think about the way that Andrew Jackson is genocidal in relationship to Native Americans. He is absolutely uninterested in Native American reproduction. So his genocidal policy is a particularly misogynistic form of racial violence, right? Andrew Jackson as a slave holder is interested in African-American reproduction. That's not to say that it's easier to be enslaved than it is to be Cherokee. It is, however, to say that when we think about racial capitalism in this different way, we need to think about its reproductive and sexual aspect, because that reproduction reproductive and sexual aspect is part of how these things are actually constitutive, dynamically constitutive, of racial identity rather than reflecting some sort of prior formation, racial formation. So why, finally, do I think this is important? I think it's important because it's empirically true. And I think that this is something that Tony illustrated with the story of the Amsterdam stock exchange or the VOC, that basic, at root, when you talk about the history of capital in the Atlantic world, the capital that you are talking about is in many instances human beings. So it doesn't actually make-- and so the way that I think about this is, how does the cotton trade work? Well, the cotton trade, which is the exemplar, the unquestioned exemplar, of industrial capitalist modernity, works on an advance basis where, every year, cotton merchants in Great Britain make advances to American merchant bankers who make advances to planters. Well, one thing about cotton merchants and merchant bankers is that they're greedy, and they're not stupid. Which is to say, they do not make unsecured advances, right? Those advances are made against security. That security comes in two forms-- enslaved human beings or expropriated Indian land. So that is to say the capital that is at the bottom of the Atlantic commercial economy that leads to, that supports, the industrial capitalism of Liverpool, that capital is either stolen land or stolen people. So it doesn't then make sense to try to-- and this is, again, to come back to a way that Tony talked about it. It doesn't make sense to try to set up some kind of archetype, a social sciencey definition of capital and say, well, this is what we see. And capitalism has these seven forms, and we don't see that in Mississippi. The actually existing capitalism of the 19th century in that, a lot of that capital was human or stolen land. Pragmatically speaking, it's just a pleasure to be at a place called the Center for the Study of Slavery and Justice, because it's that normative ethical turn that I think our world too infrequently allows. And basically, the reason that I think it's important to try to think about the history of slavery, the history of the Atlantic world, the history of the United States, and really, the history of the world as a history of racial capitalism is because it forwards to us then a specific kind of historical subject. If one imagines that the history of capitalism is the history of Manchester, one then concludes that the universal subject of history is a white wage worker from Manchester. If one insists upon capitalism as always already racial, one imagines a different sort of historical subject as the central subject of our studies, our history, and the lessons that we can draw from history. And so that's why I would want to try to insist upon this. Thank you very much. [APPLAUSE] The plan is to have a conversation between the panel first and then move out to any questions. I'll jump in. One of the things that I've been working through recently is how early enslaved people stand in for currency. The earliest bill-- oh, there goes a chair. The earliest example that I've seen is in 1504 or 1505 in which a Spaniard describes a ship returning from Hispaniola loaded with gold when, in fact, it's loaded with slaves. But he uses the word. And they're Africans who have been rerouted back into Iberia. But he uses the words interchangeably. And they're very early instances of Africans being elided with gold or with other forms of currency and being used to pay debts. And I think that that, as you were talking about the capital at the bottom of the Atlantic commercial economy, what is really crucial to me is to think through what is the same and what is different about those 15th century moments. And which I think scholars are really interested in the way that categories of wealth and commerce are still embedded in religion. They're embedded in much earlier forms of thinking. But the leg, the forward motion, it seems to me to be in that connection, in that elision that starts out as just some people who are enslavable and turns into this entire category of people who are enslavable, but nonetheless, is wedded to the emergence of this long distance trade and exchange of goods and moneys. I did have a question that I think runs across several of the papers which starts, in a way, with Jennifer's point about race thinking as standing in for sometimes the deeper historical scholarship that is necessary to differentiate between different periods-- a question about racial capitalism in its broadest, expansive, and explanatory sense to move away from an account of capitalism abstracted from that, or an idea of slave capitalism that can articulate the specificities of a form emerging from slavery. Because I think those are three different approaches to a shared set of problems, but I think another way that when you posed your question, Jennifer, I flipped it in one sense where I was thinking too. Sometimes, actually, there is a way in which thinking about slavery removes deeper consideration of racialization and its significance as well. I think that there is a way in which we could think differently about Marx's work as not having a problem in considering slavery as part of capitalism, even though there's huge limitations to that, but actually to understand the deep significance of race and racism [? as ?] [? well. ?] Can I answer two things? One in response to Jennifer's really very good question-- as you were speaking, Jennifer, one of the things I was thinking about was that-- I don't know of an earlier period. But what I was thinking of immediately was the silver mining in Peru and the forms of indentured servitude of the Indigenous population in the large mines that the Spanish had. And then really saying that what we have perhaps in the 15th century running concurrently are forms of indenture and unfree labor and slavery and that all of these things run simultaneously. And what then is important for me is to think, therefore, that capitalism is not one regime of labor but that the unfree labor, indentured labor, and so on, are all part. Different regimes of labor actually part of the electoral system reinforced each other, are connected to each other, and therefore, opens up a different political space to begin to think about what struggles may actually look like. I think that's right. So that's what your question made me begin to think. I mean, I can't think of an earlier period. I don't know the specific answer to say, it maybe '14, '15 or whatever. But I just think that you're looking at a certain kind of transformation both in the discussion of people but also in the discussion of labor and forms of labor that are occurring at a specific historical moment. In response to Zach's question, let me say that I go between racial capitalism, Walter, and slave capitalism. Some days I say racial capitalism. Some days I say slave capitalism. And part of the reason for talking about slave capitalism is not to elide race but really is to think through this labor question in a complicated way as one can and to try and think through this question of all of forms of domination that emerge in what I'm calling in quotation marks "slave capitalism." Because what I would want to argue is that the actual construction of slavery and the transformation of the double commodification process that occurs at that moment through racial difference and so on and so forth and racial white supremacy and all of those things then also means that there is a way in which the agenda operates, in the way in which I would like to call other forms of relations of domination are then opened up. And so that's what I'm thinking of. So there's a debate, for example, in 1774 in Jamaica and in Antigua between planters about women. Because women are, when you look at the numbers, there are more women in the field than men. All right, and so they're trying to work through. Some people are saying, what is it that you are doing? You shouldn't be treating people like that. And some people are saying, no, no, they work better than that. I mean, there's a whole set of arguments. And it is only a certain point when I think that the business of the reproduction of gender and the necessity, they begin to say, OK, we need to think about how to reproduce slaves more-- that they begin to think about, OK, let's treat, as one planter [? says, ?] [? Madison. ?] We are perhaps treating these women to-- what he says, we are giving them too much hard labor. We need to rethink those questions. And so that, again, to me, is this business of, what do you do with enslaved? And how do you treat the enslaved? How do you treat those that you who have constructed as less than human and the arguments around that? But I think that that's a really good example of this thing that I sort of glossed over, that we were inheriting these categories that come to us from 18th century abolitionists. Because that's precisely a moment in which gender is functioning in a particular way to say, oh, there are women in the fields. When, in fact, what we know, sort of, but it's hard because of the evidence, is that women are between 40% and 50% of captives in the first 150 years of the slave trade. But the evidence for that is hard to come by, right? The Slave Trade Database only gives us these glimpses of it. A lot of it is in Spanish and Portuguese. And so the data isn't as-- and so what I think I know then is that for 200 years, women have been in the fields. And slave owners have been-- it's not even a subject of conversation. But then it becomes a subject of conversation for many reasons at the end of the 18th century. And then that woman stands in in the same way that Walter talked about, Sylvia Wynter's-- that universal woman who is not African, who's not enslaved, but who then gets applied to this woman of African descent in the fields. It's confusing, right? So then it means that we need a new way to talk about how gender is operating in the first 100 years of enslavement. But I think that it's a really good point. Yeah, I agree. It's usually schematic. But as far as trying to imagine the history of the changing categories, I think it is probably fair to say that, by and large, the categories of the Atlantic slave trade are categories of nationality. Yes. Coromantee, Igbo-- and that the categories of the era of slavery that happens after the Atlantic slave trade are increasingly racial categories-- the Negro, Garifuna, mulatto. And that then has a sexual aspect, a sexual regulatory, racial aspect. And so I think that one of the things I'd want to do then with the notion of racial capitalism is to try to actually track that argument out so one could make it in writing rather than just saying it and to say that the invention. So Robinson dates the invention of the Negro to the moment of the slave trade. And the invention of the Negro is the notion of someone who is evacuated from history and is thus infinitely comparable to other Negros. I don't actually think that's empirically what happens with the slave trade, because I think there is all of this reckoning through national stereotypes and that the invention of the Negro, in Robinson's sense, is the invention of a more familiarly racialist discourse of anti-blackness, say, that is focused on direct biological lineage and a certain kind of notion of sexual regulation. That does seem to me, at least in the smaller knowledge that I have about the United States, that does happen with the closing of the slave trade and then the beginning of a set of commercial comparisons around these different kinds of imagined aspects of racial difference. I had a question for Seth, if I could. Because I was thinking about the way you ended, the loom with parts from South Carolina and France and the wool. And I guess, like how far back do you want to-- because I think that what both Walter and Tony have asked us to frame this history of capitalism-- I don't know. And again, if you remember, I said I wasn't a scholar of capitalism. [INAUDIBLE] [INAUDIBLE] Yeah. So how would you frame? Because the moment that you're talking about feels very connected to what I understand as industrial, right? It's about the production of goods and then connecting that through understanding that it's being deeply embedded in the history of slavery. How much earlier do you want to think about the history of things that are moving around and that are produced by slave labor? Well, I think one would study the flows of commodities into West African slaving ports in the 16th century and basically tracing them back to Gujarat or to Wales or to Amsterdam or wherever it might be. And I think that process of early modern global integration runs through the slave trade, runs through the development of new incentives to produce goods that will find buyers in West Africa fundamentally. And I see an increasingly growing population. This helps us rethink, for instance, the Industrial Revolution. Why are European households in the 17th century engaging in what one economic historian calls "a mode of self exploitation," working themselves harder, devoting more of their familial labor to producing things for the market? What are the incentives? Well, the incentives are, of course, things that enslaved people have grown in the Americas like sugar. And the incentives are to produce things that can be then vended in West Africa. And so I think some of the largest transformations that precede the Industrial Revolution as part of early modern global history very much run through the slave trade. And I would put that at the center. That's terrific. I would say I absolutely agree. And point to France, and point to [? Nod, ?] the city of [? Nod, ?] and the [? Lower ?] Valley and the river that those boats came up in the 1600s before they went to Africa and then to [? San Der Mar, ?] and that a stone's throw, a literal stone's throw, from where those boats came in was a factory of nearly 4,000 workers making textiles that were then that were taken from India and were redone because of the market in West Africa. And so you have to think about those workers just a stone's throw away from the ships so that the things can be carried to the ships and how it comes from India to them first. They remake it in a certain style, which the West Africans [INAUDIBLE]. From the perspective of global economic history, then all of a sudden, we need Asia in this story. We need China as the sun around which the early modern global economy orbits. So how is it that most New World silver ends up in Chinese coffers? That has to be part of-- slavery has to be part of that story, and that story has to be part of the story of slavery. Absolutely. So I think it gets very big very quickly. Can we open up the floor for conversation? If people have questions, I think we have about a half an hour for continued conversation. Have a go. Thank you for this conversation. I have a question for Jennifer. I'm really interested about what you were saying about 1504 is the first moment in which you see people [? acting ?] [INAUDIBLE] [? or ?] whatever. So I see this as a moment where you have a category of people are under you, so to say. And I'm just wondering to what extent you see or if you're tracing the ways in which this knowledge about folks as subjects transferred to the English colonies 100 years later? Do you trace that? How do you see that happening? It's happening in 1504 versus what's happening in 17th century Virginia and the laws? To me, I've always relied a lot on the circulation of travel accounts and the way that stories are both published and are told by and translated into English and then circulate in England. I've been reading a lot of 1620 pamphlet literature about-- it's so thrilling. That's serious. About currency and about what happens when English coin leaves the land, and the people, the men, who are associated with this kind of early theorizing about the economy are deeply concerned about what the Spanish have done in the past 100 years. And so there's an enormous-- there's a lot of attention that's being paid to the Spanish in the Americas as well as on the African coast. Can i just follow up really quickly? Yeah. Do you find that connected to the race in which the Virginians were denying the bonded African from their humanness in the legal laws that came by? And do you find that in a discussion of how to justify denying you know African-descended free people from testifying or what have you, is that connected to this discussion? That discussion, I actually don't know. I've written about both things. But my focus on the history of the law in colonial Virginia is really through more formal legal history rather than this kind of swirling space of overlap. So I'm just going to say I'm going to think about that. I think it's a really good question. [INAUDIBLE] question. Comment to Jennifer-- and thank you for the presentation. When you mentioned interchangeable between gold and slave, it's worth mentioning that the Taino were exterminated in the trade industry from Europe to Hispaniola. And the reason why that happened was because they fought to the T for what they thought belonged to them and nothing but. There were 25,000 [? river ?] in Hispaniola that were destroyed completely, tried to explore the gold. So when they were going to Hispaniola, they were taking gold. And in exchange, they were bringing [? nonsense. ?] And then when they realized that the island was so agriculturally productive, because they already have the tobacco and the yucca, they decided to bring and export the slave, or the Negro, who, in Hispaniola, was not a despicable term at the beginning. It was a way because the Taino were Negro, black color, dark color. And they wanted to embrace that. So when the African came, in terms of slavery, they didn't know it was slavery. It was bringing people to cultivate the land. And then they realized that there were people, the owner coming in, to take over. So that's how it happens that they were bringing gold. And the reason why Hispaniola got attacked by different corner, if you look at the south west, they were England's, who created the mulatto image change, and then you look at the west saddled with the north, it's the white, or say, from Spain. So there was an interchange of trade where, if you look at the history, Hispaniola was the land of trade to America since Christopher Columbus. Thank you for that. I would just say that by the time Columbus, by the time the first enslaved Africans are transported to Hispaniola, enslaved people have been sold in Portugal and Spain for over 50 years. So there was a there was a depth of grappling with who was enslavable and where they could be enslaved from and where they could be sold to that had already been going on for half a century at that point. So I think that part of what I'm interested in is unpacking that. So thank you. There's a question over there. Oh, sure. Hi, I had a question for Walter. I was thinking about-- well, actually it's kind of a question for Dr. Bogues as well-- thinking about the way of putting these long questions together. So you referenced three or four or five different forms of capitalist reproduction. But how do we ask questions, particularly long questions such as issues pertaining to settler colonization? How do we ask [? long dura ?] questions or tell long [? dura ?] stories when we have different temporal periods where different things are occurring? Those two things seem very difficult to reconcile. Do you have a little bit of advice on that? Because I am working through that right now. It's a terrific question. And I think the point is to recognize and to embrace exactly what you said, which is that it's a complex rather than a simple relationship. And it's also complex because the different sorts of struggles that emerge out of these historical experiences are different, right? The opposition to settler colonialism is a focus on sovereignty. And so that's a different kind of political mobilization than opposition to slavery. And so there's an enormous complexity to it, just as there are also a tremendous and complicated overlap, most obvious in the case of the dispossession of the southeastern tribes and the emergence of the cotton kingdom, right? But more complicated, so for instance, in relationship to the history of St. Louis that I'm interested in. St. Louis, among other things, was the administrative and technical, practical center of the Indian wars. St. Louis is also the place from which we get the first black soldiers in the United States Army in 1861, who then become the bedrock of the 9th and 10th Cavalry, the Buffalo Soldiers. And so there's a bend through the Buffalo Soldiers, and I think this is something that Du Bois embraces and thinks about. There's a offering of a certain kind of martial freedom to African-American men after the Civil War that is embedded in US imperialism. It's enormously complicated and not always synchronous stories. In a way, your question is-- I think that that's like a footnote to your question just simply to say the question is actually the answer. You got to just embrace it. Yeah, I agree with Walter. I think the [? long dura ?] is to think about questions of colonialism and slavery. One of the difficulties we have in US history is, in my view, that we don't think about other [INAUDIBLE].. We tend to think about slavery and so on and the revolution. But the actual thing that actually was part of British America for many years was, I think, really very important. You can't think about that colonial project in the Americas without thinking of all forms of slavery or unfree labor. You just can't. So if you think about if you're moving from the United States to, say, Latin America, you have to think about both questions of slavery and indentured for the Indigenous population. In the same way, you have to think about that question. In the Caribbean, you have to think about, again, forms of genocide, [? religious ?] forms of [? colonialism ?] and then enslaved and plantation labor. So to me, it's in thinking about the [INAUDIBLE] [? isn't ?] thinking colonialism and slavery and that relationship and how that relationships actually shapes each other but also, quite frankly, [INAUDIBLE].. And what I think people have [INAUDIBLE] and so on, this is that. In other words, it is not just I think this is slavery exactly. This is the actual centrality of the colonial project to European history. And Marx himself, I think, misses it as well. He writes some things on colonialism and so on. But the actual centrality of colonialism to the world and to the shaping of the making of the world is something that was not really thought through, I think, [? to ?] [? answer ?] your question. That's what I see. I think it's a great question. And unfortunately, [? we ?] [? want ?] [INAUDIBLE].. Can I ask a question and try to answer a question that may be in the back of the question? Which is that I do think that for projects such as the one you just gave a thumbnail of, there was a couple of very powerful, emergent bodies of thought that you're going to have to navigate around. And I think it's extremely important to navigate around them. One is an idea that racial derogation in the United States of America is fundamentally and really solely anti-blackness, and the Native Americans have always been honorary whites. And the other is that African Americans are, in fact, settler imperialist adjuncts. The reason that I [? rebel ?] in relationship to those two bodies of thought, think, insist upon, racial capitalism, just because I think that one wants to work through all of the complexity and the ways that people have unquestionably been pitted against one another to try to really develop a critique of white supremacy out of that complexity rather than what seemed to me to be kind of an emergent invidious politics in different sectors of thought. Thank you. I really like the work that you've all been doing problematizing categories. And I might riff for a moment off something Jennifer said. I think the concepts of freedom and democracy also make people lazy. If you have those, you don't have to think anymore. And I wondered whether some or all of you might like to speak to how the tools and perspectives we gain from problematizing and entangling slavery and capitalism also give us ways to think about social and economic justice today. For example, a giant multinational company that pays no tax might feel that, well, they're providing jobs. And without them, millions of people would fade away. But on the other hand, what does it mean to actually recognize a person as a person? Because one of the differences between slavery and freedom is this recognition of personhood. But if your wage structure is such that a person effectively has just enough calories to work and then they then can't do anything else, isn't that treating a person like a toaster? You put them in a cupboard with the light off and no electricity when they're not working. But I wonder whether there are other concepts that then become problematized like dominoes from slavery capitalism to freedom and democracy. My secret title for a whole bunch of my intellectual work is Against Freedom. And so I think that, in a way, what Jennifer's talking about and what Tony's talking about is the historical foreshortening of actual human emancipation into something that is basically a liberal notion of freedom. And so I think it's an absolutely integrable part of the project. And I think that in the United States, you can see it happen. The history of Reconstruction is a history of the foreshortening of a radical possibility of human emancipation into what comes to be known as freedom. It seems to me. Yeah. And I think that there's all of the categories that we are working. The challenge is that sometimes in your effort to come up with a way of historicizing the category you get, you drown in language. And I think that that's why, for example, reading Cedric Robinson is so challenging, or reading Sylvia Wynter is. Because they didn't drown in language, but they are exemplifying how difficult it is to unpack the damage that's done to our conceptual capacities by the afterlife of slavery, that our categories are foreshortened, that we imagine that there are these antitheses of slavery and freedom, for example, to name just one, or that there are places that are culture versus economy versus-- I don't know. It's very hard to write that clearly and smartly, I find. Yeah. So I had a methodological question. It's something I'm wrestling with personally as I'm writing my book manuscript. So the sort of neo-Marxian model is you have base superstructure. As Professor Johnson, you just said, if racism and economic exploitation are usually constituting, that's obviously not a base superstructure model. So how do you work in this intersection between cultural and political economy? I guess. I'm [? not ?] [? sure. ?] Are you trying to say that I'm a cultural Marxist? [LAUGHTER] I would never. I would never do such a thing. But the practical nuts and bolts, how do you work in the intersection of these two different approaches, as you all do in your work? That's why I want to insist on racial capitalism. I mean, and so if you look at, for instance, this fantastic debate between Ta-Nehisi Coates and Cedric Johnson, where Cedric Johnson writes this fantastically sharp critique of Coates. And he says, well, everything for Coates is about race. And that's true. Coates is a nationalist. He's an intellectual nationalist. And so he must see everything as white supremacy-- his superstructure, in the terms that you outlined. Robinson comes back. He says, no, no, everything is about class. Everything's about base, right? And in fact, what we have is a set of ideologies that are masking material exploitation that is fundamentally class exploitation. I think here you have two brilliant people who are talking past one another. And the missing term is Du Bois. The missing term is racial capitalism. I think Du Bois does it brilliantly. And so I try not to get too-- and maybe this is just because I haven't quite got there intellectually to be able to really directly answer your question. I try not to get too into priors. I just don't see. Ideas have a material history, right? Every encounter with the material is always already a cultural encounter with materials. I try not to. I try to use metaphors that are about simultaneity and hybridity or saturation. And it's possible that that's just me not having figured out an answer to your question. But I just think that those priors that we've been given are not super helpful. They're not realistic. When do we ever in our own lives actually separate ideation from the [INAUDIBLE]?? I just don't see it happen. So for me then, I guess I'm coming around to an answer. And the answer, as do so many other things, is along with Du Bois, [? Ramon ?] [? Williams. ?] Marxism in literature is, for me, a real touchstone in that. I think that part of the difficulty has been a certain capital reading of Marx's [INAUDIBLE] The German Ideology, which then sets up this superstructure argument. And part of that is class, race. So race is ideology. Class is foundational because it is rooted in economic and productive things. Where I like to think about it is that we, quite frankly, are moving from Williams through [? Stewart ?] through Sylvia Wynter is that we might want to think about, rather than thinking about modes of production, which then gets you back into trying to think whether the base is there, superstructure is there, what's the relationship, is it dialectical-- what comes first, the chicken or the egg-- and so on and so forth? You might want to think about something called production of the humor. And go back to something that actually Marx says in Capital, which is that economic relations are relations between people. It is something that we use. And if economic relationship are essential relations between people, then what is important is this set of relationships between human beings that are formed in material-- provision, and living, and so on and so forth. And therefore, what might be important is the certain production of what we are and who we are at specific moments. I mean, that's how I try to sidestep that particular question, which means that one is not working as a kind of cultural [? ferries ?] or a political economy is over there and I'm so on. But actually, one is trying to think through simultaneously. In other words, as we produce certain material things, [? provisional, ?] you can engage in material things for provisioning and so on and so forth, that simultaneously, we are actually producing narratives about ourselves as we do this. So it's not one comes first. It is almost a certain simultaneity, right? And then trying to think, OK, how then do you as a scholar work within that and become? So the word, operational word, for methodology is complexity. And I'm not trying to find one master key. It's like, aha, now I have it, and I can then open the door to knowledge. I don't think so. I think it is really trying to understand those simultaneous things to understand that societies are an assemblage rather than a kind of structure, hard set of social structure. And therefore, if you understand it that way, then you understand relationality and then try to work through those things. i don't [INAUDIBLE]. But that's [? all I ?] [? have. ?] Yeah, I really wanted to ask. How does Du Bois seem to think about having to live without slavery in the future? The answer might be very easy to you. I don't know. But for me, it's very hard when grappling with it, at least because I read one of the books. I think it's an amazing work, but different from work that I'm used to. That is, it's called Suicide of the West. It's written by Jonah Goldberg. If you [? don't ?] [? do ?] The National Review, so you could tell. But he tries to downplay the role that slavery plays in the history of capital. And that is something that I think is intellectually concerning. So I just wanted to pose that question to you. Yeah, it's actually-- I've gotten around. I've made a career out of saying outrageous things. But the one that actually really seems to drive people crazy is that if you say that there's no capitalism without slavery. And when you say there's no capitalism without slavery, economists start coming to your talks. And then they're crazy. It drives them crazy. And I think that is empirically the case. I just don't see how you could argue otherwise. I just don't see how you could do it. So then the question that leads me to is, well, let's do some intellectual history of the effort to separate those things. And I think that's an intellectual issue that goes well beyond the reaction to the Williams thesis. I think that's an intellectual history that would take you to the very foundation of the notion of economic history, right? So why is it the case? Why is it an interesting question? Why is it interesting to say, well, I don't know. Only 25% of the industrial capacity of Great Britain is focused on at a particular moment in time is focused on producing cotton, and there's another 25% focused on producing linen. And linen is not an imperial crop. And so what we can do is we can see that this might have happened. Industrialisation and development might have happened on the basis of linen and other sorts of domestic non-imperial, non-slave produced crops if we can just get rid of this 25% that has to do with slavery? What kind of question is that? That's a ridiculous way to think. It's a bizarre way to think. And it seems like a regular way to think because we've all become inured to social science reasoning. So the question then is, well, where does this form of reasoning come from? And what does it have to do with derogating the role of African, African-American, and other imperialized people in the production of modernity, right? So now, that's a huge intellectual project that I don't have the chops to do myself. But I actually think that that's there. I would love to see that history. But and Walter, can I just say? I think that that's-- this book project that I'm very, very close to being finished with started with suddenly seeing the notion. The people who originate the idea of political arithmetic, demography, and the scholarship on political economy that's organized around 17th century England, the men who are writing this are invested in the slave trade. And yet, historians and political economists and political theorists treat them as completely distinct historiographical phenomena. So you have an enormous amount of scholarship on the economy of the slave trade and on slavery in the 17th century and then an enormous amount of scholarship on the history of political economy. And they're completely separate. They literally do not. I mean, you can have a work on-- and this is terrible, because this is a straw man. But Mary Poovey's History of the Modern Fact, which is about the emergence of double entry bookkeeping and accounting practices that happens at the moment, and slavery doesn't even appear in the index of that work. And it's as if the question-- how could that be? And so for me, I don't know how to answer that question. Because again, as I keep on wanting to say, I'm not a historian of capitalism. I'm a historian of slavery. And so I only ever ask questions from the perspective of the history of slavery or enslavement. But I don't find your statement at all provocative, Walter. Well, yeah. [LAUGHTER] We've been in the [? same world. ?] We're on the same team. And with that, we do have to end. Sorry, Walter. If we could give one last of applause. [APPLAUSE] Thank you. [INAUDIBLE]
Info
Channel: Watson Institute for International and Public Affairs
Views: 231,493
Rating: undefined out of 5
Keywords: Watson Institute, Watson International Institute, Brown University, Brown u, Brown, Public Affairs
Id: 0DJkIRriNZ8
Channel Id: undefined
Length: 118min 58sec (7138 seconds)
Published: Mon Jan 14 2019
Related Videos
Note
Please note that this website is currently a work in progress! Lots of interesting data and statistics to come.