Robert Solow in Conversation with Paul Krugman: "Inequality: What Can Be Done?"

Video Statistics and Information

Video
Captions Word Cloud
Reddit Comments
Captions
- I'm Janet Gornick, I'm sitting in the library of the Russel Sage Foundation where I'm joined by Bob Solow and Paul Krugman. We're here today to hear them share their thoughts about a new book by Tony Atkinson called Inequality: What can be done? which is being published by Harvard University Press this month I'm especially happy to be here wearing my hat as the director of LIS, the Cross-National Data Center in Luxembourg where Tony Atkinson has served as a crucial advisor to us for 30 years. He now serves as the board president. He's been an invaluable advisor to all of us at LIS, and to the many inequality scholars who've used our data over so many years. Let's get started, Bob and Paul, welcome. As I mentioned to you both, I'm gonna organize our conversation today drawing loosely on a framework offered by the American sociologist Eric Wright. What I wanna draw on is his idea of the real utopia. As I think you know by now, a real utopia is a proposed institutional or policy arrangement that's designed in the service of an end goal. The utopia part is of course, straightforward, and the idea of a real utopia is that many of its components are imaginable and that they exist in whole, or in part. In other words, it's a utopian image, but it's not science fiction, it's in the world of the real. In my view, this package that Tony has proposed, Tony Atkinson, that forms the core of the book is really very much like what Wright has described as a real utopia. The reason I wanted to think about that is that he offers what I think is a useful framework for thinking about and even evaluating policy proposals. The suggest is that there are three distinctions, three distinct dimensions that we should think about. One is their desirability. Are the stated end goals desirable? The second is the viability. Will the proposed package bring about these proposed and stated goals? Third, the achievability. Is there some feasibility politically? I drew on this framework when I put these questions together just to get us organized, because the book is of course, wide ranging and also quite intricate. Let me first start on the issue of desirability. The book, of course, is framed around Tony's call for reduced inequality, and the main focus is on income inequalities, specifically the income distributions. The first question I think perhaps obvious, but useful, especially for an American audience I think is why are we concerned about inequality? Tony notes in the book, of course, that many argue that we should worry about inequality for instrumental reasons. It leads to a range of social ills and it damages the democratic process, but then he adds a quote, "And then there are those like me "who believe that the present levels of economic inequality "are intrinsically inconsistent "with the conception of a good society." What are your views on this? Why are we concerned about inequality? - First of all, I do think it's important that extreme inequality is bad for the democratic political process, and has all sorts of other things. Personally, I find extremes of high income, and extreme poverty repulsive. I think that's immoral in effect. This is a little bit combining, or mixing up, the question of poverty and the high incomes, the top incomes. I don't mind people being a lot richer than I am, that doesn't bother me so much. It does bother me when there are people who are very much poorer than I am. I think it's a bad society that tolerates extreme poverty in the presence of high incomes and high productivity, so it could clearly do better. - [Janet] Paul? - Yeah, I have two thoughts. The first one is pretty well fleshed out, which is I am, and I think lots of us are, to some degree Rawlsians. That is, we think that at some level, you ought to think about society in terms of what would you want if you didn't know who you would be, behind the veil of ignorance. You don't have to be a rigorous Rawlsian to feel that it is right, it's appropriate to care more about diminishing misery at the bottom than increasing comfort at the top. That if you can transfer a billion dollars worth of purchasing powers from there to there. Even if it's leaky bucket, which we're not clear it is, that that is a good thing from the point of view of some notion of justice. There's something, I think, my second point which is a little bit vaguer. It's not just the functioning of democracy, but there is a kind of a democratic goal, a democratic idea which is not purely political. It's an idea of something like equal dignity that even though, yes some people, no one expects exact equality or something close to it, but the idea that everyone feels correctly that they are being treated as a person of equal worth with other people. Extreme inequality is inconsistent with that, you're just not gonna be able to have that kind of society when people are in an entirely different material universes. - Yeah, I think there's a lot of truth to that. The French novelist, Anatole France, once said that, "Freedom is the right of the rich as well as the poor "to sleep under the bridges of Paris," and there is an element of that. Citizenship requires a certain degree of equality. - Let me push on and ask the question to sort of turn the fine lens on the goal here. What exactly are we aiming for? I was taken by this. Tony writes in the book, quote, "The goal is to reduce inequality "below its current level in the belief that "the current level of inequality is excessive. "I've stated this proposition deliberately "in terms of the direction of movement, "not of the ultimate destination." My question for you, is that satisfying, is that sufficient? Paul, what do you think? - It is for me, in fact I think it's right. If you ask me exactly how much, Paul already said, no one can aim for or even believe in the possibility of everybody having exactly the same income, the same wealth, the same this, the same that. If you ask me what degree of inequality we should aim for, what Gini coefficient is the right coefficient, I couldn't answer. It's like Mr. Justice Stewart in pornography, I don't know how to define it, but I know it when I see it. I feel the same way about inequality. I see the inequality in the U.S., and it's obviously too great. It would do us no harm, and in fact as a society, do us a lot of good if the extremes were moved closer to the center, and I think that's the right attitude with which to approach the problem. - In a way this comes back to the question of real utopias. The reality of what can be achieved, we know, is not going to be getting anywhere close to the level of equality that Bob and I and Tony would want in our lifetimes. You don't really need to know where the resting point should be. I think if you did ask me, the way I would put is that if we could get inequality back to the sorts of levels that prevailed in Western Europe 30, 40 years ago, if we could get it back to the level that prevailed among the white population in the United States 40 years ago, I'm not sure that you would say that that was any kind of ideal, but it would certainly greatly reduce the priority of the issue. I think that's all that we need to say at this point, that if we could get back to those levels, then it would become an interesting discussion whether further reductions in inequality were a good thing, but it wouldn't be urgent, but now it is. - So it sounds like you're concerned in the U.S. case both by the high level but also by the rise in recent decades, is that correct? - [Robert] Yes, certainly. - Yes, although I think mostly the higher level. I think it's just that we, and the transformation of society, that that society of equal dignity. Okay, we never were that entirely, but we were a lot closer to it when I was growing up than we are now. - Let me ask another question about, again, this end vision, to use the framework of the real utopia. Tony had some very pointed things to say in the book about the relationship between inequality of opportunity and inequality of outcome, and arguing essentially, I would say, that these cannot and should not be viewed distinctly. This is of course a long standing discussion in the United States. What are your thoughts about that? - I would go a lot further than Tony did on this issue. You show me a political figure, let's say, who goes on and on about how what we want is equality of opportunity, not equality of outcome, and I'll show you a phony. Everyone knows, everyone's mother knows, everyone's mother-in-law knows that you cannot have widespread of income extremes of rich and poor, and suppose that the children of those families have equal opportunity. It helps a lot to have a good diet when you're young, to be well taken care of, and well dressed, and warm, and comfortable, and to go to a good school, and to be able to contact your parents' friends when you're looking for a job. It's just ridiculous to suppose that an unequal society can have equality of opportunity. I think the people who prat along know that, so they just prattle on. - Not too much to add, except of course we have hard evidence on this as well. We have long term studies where we can have some evidence of inherent talent and also, of course, socioeconomic status and then we have outcomes, and we know that rich, dumb kids are more likely to graduate college than smart, poor kids, and many other things as well. This is overwhelmingly the case. If you wanna talk about unreal utopias, the notion that you can have a highly unequal society where every kid has an equal chance at making it to the top, that's really unreal. - That would take one large kabootz, is what it would take. - Talk about the causality though. I'm interested, you know, there's a lot of discussion about this so-called get speaker although many think it's sort of oddly named, this scatter plot, you know showing across countries that intergenerational mobility is negatively correlated with, in the cross section, inequality. I think the negative correlation is fairly strongly established, but what's the causality? What is really the like, the examples you gave, Bob, about children were really more about poverty than inequality if I'm understanding this right. - I don't distinguish so clearly between poverty and inequality since we're used, in this country, to trying to define poverty absolutely. There's a poverty line, if you're below it, you're poor, if you're above it, you're non-poor or whatever. Europeans and others, in fact practically everywhere else in the world define poverty relatively. You're poor if you have an income which is less than two thirds the median, or less than one half the median, you can choose the number. I don't think it's just a matter of poverty. We could all be, to use the great American empty phrase, middle class, and those who are at the top of the middle class (chuckles) would have a better shot at a good life than those who are at the bottom of the middle class. - There's so many channels through which privilege gets conveyed to the next generation. Some of them are very raw, like having enough to eat when you're a child, or having adequate medical care. Some of them are fairly subtle, like knowing people who can give your son or daughter an internship, right? There's a whole range of different types of things. There's no cut off that says as long as you have a family income of $23,000 a year, then you have full access for everything society has to offer. It's just very clear that you don't have to, it's impossible to enumerate because there would be hundreds and hundred of channels. - The book that got so much attention last year, the book by Thomas Picketty, which of course you both know well, and I know you both reviewed. One of the discussions that came out after the book, one of the lines of criticism was that poverty sort of disappeared, and that there was actually not very much said about the middle and the bottom, and we know of course some of that is because of the data that were used. Tony sees this differently. He seems to see less possibility for looking, or less value for looking only at a single part of the distribution. What do you think about that? - I think the books are different. They're about different things in a way. Piketty has tried to give us a grand, historical sweep, a vision which is focused on the top, because that's where the data are in the distant past. And he's actually pretty thin on solutions, it's more about here's what's happening. He's not really talking about society as a whole, either, as he talking about this aspect. Tony is giving us a checklist of things to do, informed by research, and it's a little bit funny because actually Tony pioneered the kind of quantitative research that Piketty has made such a global story about. But still, it's just different purposes. I don't see any contradiction between them, but if I, asking, what can we do, what can the next President, or maybe the two Presidents further down the line when the political situation loosens up a bit more, what can be done in Chelsea Clinton's second term? Tony's book is the one that's gonna provide much more guidance. - Yeah. I generally agree with all that. The lesson I learned from the great stir that Thomas Piketty's book aroused, with its focus on the 1% or the tenth of 1%, is that envy is a stronger emotion than compassion in people. I think it was a very valuable book, apart from the massive data and thought that went into it, which was valuable by itself. I think it was a very valuable book because it brought the issue into the public arena sharply in a way that no amount of talking about the lower tail of the income distribution could ever have done. You have to work at both of those things, if we want, and Tony's book does. If you want to create a more equal society, you're gonna have to do things. One of them is to pull the upper tail closer to the median, and the other is to pull the lower tail closer to the median, so it's compression that we want. - Let me turn our attention now to what I've been calling the viability access. Paul you just sort of gave us a good introduction to this. Let me just clarify what I mean by that. I want you to think now about these 15 proposals, or a subset of them, without being constrained, at least for the next 20 minutes by questions of political achievability, let's bracket that. Essentially, for each of them, or for all of them as a whole, is the case for cause and effect sound, what about unintended consequences? Let me just remind you and alert the video audience that Tony puts forth a package of 15 proposals. Early reviewers of the book have noted, and I think we probably would agree, that they range from the familiar to the novel. The 15 proposals cover a lot of territory. Two relate to technology, two relate to employment and pay, three of them relate to the treatment of capital, four to progressive taxation, and four to social security. What I'd like to hear you do is reflect on which of them, maybe mention three or four, or as you wish, struck you as the most intriguing, or creative, or perhaps the most promising. - The ones I particularly liked in Tony's book are those that are not about redistribution, but about effecting how income gets distributed by the market. I was particularly interested in the labor market questions, or proposals, some of them struck me as more useful than others. You may remember that Tony is worried, and so am I, about what I'll call the casualization of employment. He goes on at some length about the increasing temporary employment, the increasing fixed contract employment, the increasing part-time employment. People in jobs like that, the numbers have been increasing, and if they increase further in the future, people like that have very little bargaining power about wages. They have very little claim on the firm as an institution to which they belong, in fact they have no claim on the firm as an institution to which they belong. Finding ways, almost certainly through public policy, of providing more protection or bargaining power or wages for people in those classes strike me as very important, and Tony speaks of legislation to make it easier for trade unions to represent workers. It's gonna be hard for trade unions to represent causal workers, because there's no stable membership to worry about, but maybe that could be worked out. He talked about a social and economic council to have a conversation. I tend to be pessimistic about the viability of that. You can have a lot of conversation, but who is listening is more the point, and so I don't see that. He did speak about a pay policy, a wage policy, for the country consisting of a relatively high minimum wage and a set of rules or standards or I don't know how to describe it, but ways in which businesses ought to look at the setting of wages. If any kind of force can be put behind those, I think those would be extremely important. Maybe by changes in corporate governments, maybe by changing the representation on boards of directors, maybe by statute, I don't know. But those are the things that interested me particularly. - Bob scooped me to a fair bit because I also, I think in some ways the most interesting, for me, the most interesting thing and welcome thing in Tony's book is the emphasis on pre tax and transfer inequality. His argument that you can do quite a lot on that front, which is something I agree with and in fact is something that's been a kind of, I've been told it's a new movement among liberal economists in the U.S. I didn't know I was part of a movement, though apparently I am. It's- - [Robert] What makes you think there's a movement of liberal economists in the U.S.? (laughs) - I know, all three of us. Anyway, but no, Tony talks about enhancing, basically making the environment easier for labor organizing, enhancing collective bargaining. I would actually put minimum wage at a living wage standard, it's in that same domain. Social economic council, just a moral suasion and effect to tilt the balance, which I think is, it's terribly important because we do ... It means among other things for it not being fatalistic about the market distribution of income. There has been this strong tendency for the past several decades to say, "Well the gods of the market set wages, and yes, "maybe you can tax and provide aid afterwards, "but there's nothing you can do," and that looks like it's not true. There's actually quite a lot of research, quite a lot of evidence, historical recent that says it's not true. Supply and demand is much less of a rigid determinant of the distribution of pre-tax income than current mythology has it, which means that there's room to operate on that front, and that I think could matter quite a lot. I think it was very interesting that Tony makes full employment an inequality policy, which turns out, I mean ... It's funny, if you really believed in competitive markets, it's not at all clear why a depressed economy should work, it should hurt everybody, it should especially hurt labor, but practice shows that that doesn't seem to be true, that full employment is actually very important for the share of workers and income, and the share of less well paid workers and income. Tony, interestingly, proposes not just the useful fiscal and monetary policies, but in fact, the government as employer of last resort, which is a very old-fashioned idea, except probably a very good one, and one of those things that ... We've had this kind of, again, fatalism. We're now in year eight of this ongoing world economic slump, and it's kind of, "Well, we've tried this, we've tried that," but really, full employment either will happen or it doesn't, whereas Tony is saying just make it happen, and that, I think, is certainly right analytically. Tony does have a set of proposals that I think are interesting, intriguing, and I don't agree with (chuckles) which is his various things about basically trying to make ordinary families capitalists, guaranteed positive real return on savings up to a certain point, an effect of government provided bequest when you reach adulthood, and those are all, they're nice things, but I think it's, that's an ultimately futile effort. The fact of the matter is wealth is always gonna be vastly more unequally distributed than income. Most people are going to, never going to have a significant amount of their income coming from capital, and I would prefer that we just acknowledge that and say that you do not have to be, we don't have to be an ownership society, that people don't have to be mini capitalists to be full-fledged members of our society. But that's the interesting thing, is Tony has these arguments, and other people have made them, but it's actually some place where I would actually not wanna follow him. - I agree on these things with Paul. We can't get any controversy there. I forgot to mention the full employment notion, and the government as employer of last resort, both of which I think are very, very useful ideas. I too am suspicious, or at least unexcited by the capital grant at age 18. I'm not clear what is accomplished by giving an 18 year old roughly the equivalent of $15,000, and why? What happens then? You don't start a small business, it won't pay for much education, the education could be provided in other ways, if put in a bank account and grow at a small, real rate of interest, it will amount to something, but I don't think that that's the way to handle retirement either. I think, and by the way, in Tony's book, he has another recommendation about major improvement in social security, and that I think is the way to do this. I do wanna add one redistributive proposal he makes that is interesting to me. We talked earlier about how you can't have equality of opportunity in an unequal society. One of Tony's proposals would kind of eat away at the inequality of opportunity, and that's a sort of cumulative tax on inheritances so that the very wealthy can't pass on their status, their wealth status, to their kids by a series of gifts during their lifetime, and then leaving some more to them when they die. The idea of making it cumulative so that no lucky offspring can become wealthy over time simply by waiting for parental money to drop into the basket, that strikes me as a very useful thing. We're not to talk about achievability yet, but of course I can't help remembering that the Congress has been trying to eliminate the pitiful estate tax that we have, and here is someone who wants to make something that's effective, but that would generate some equality of opportunity, or at least improve the equality of opportunity. - Tony talks about the basic income in the form of a child allowance, which I think also brings us back to the opportunity question. I think you all know that in the Cameron years, the child allowance, which used to be universal, was means tested, so a means test was set quite high in Tony's estimate, and I've heard Holly Suttilan say the same, I think he notes something like 700,000 children are now no longer on the child benefit there. What he argues for is, and I think it can be extended to other benefits of course, making it universal, removing the means test and having it taxed. I think, Bob, I've heard you speak in favor of that idea, is that correct? - Yeah, I think that's a splendid idea. I think our, means testing sounds so plausible. Why waste this on people who don't need it? We know two things about means tested benefits. One is, and I believe, if I remember rightly, Tony mentions both of these things. One of them is that they're never fully taken up. If you offer a means tested benefit, there will be many, many eligible people who simply, for one reason or another, maybe because they think it stigmatizes them in some way, maybe for some, maybe ignorance, maybe some other reason, they don't do it. Even so, kind of normal a benefit as the earned income tax credit, which you know, is part of the tax return, the 1040 and all that, it sounds so natural. There are many, many eligible people who don't take it up. Means testing eliminates part of the benefit, part of the good that a benefit can do. The second problem is that it's very difficult, maybe impossible, to design an effective means tested benefit that doesn't end up with an excessively high marginal tax rate on the beneficiaries as they earn their way out of the benefit, as their means increase. Phasing out seems always to involve a very high marginal tax rate, and so it provides a bad incentive, and it's no good from that point of view. The idea of non-means tested benefits, especially a child benefit, which also bears on the equality of opportunity issue, but that kind of thing, and making it just taxable as normal income, that sounds far more sensible to me. - Just to actually follow up on everything Bob said. On the people not taking it up, we have a lovely illustration right now as the Affordable Care Act is implemented, as you know half the states have refused to expand Medicaid, which in itself is a fairly incredible thing, for free. Nonetheless, there's a substantial increase in the Medicaid roles even in those states. The law hasn't changed any, but people have heard, "Oh, there's this thing called Medicaid, "I might be eligible for it." People are calling them wood workers, which is actually a very good thing, this is a very important benefit. Means tested programs are complicated. You have to apply, you have to know about it, and often people don't, so a universal benefit works much better. The marginal tax rate issue, you wanna think about that as a trade-off. You save a little bit of money by means testing, which means that tax rates on higher incomes can be lower, so you're in effect trading off a slightly lower marginal tax rate on higher incomes for an often much higher marginal tax rate on lower incomes, and almost certainly that's a bad trade-off to make. I think there's something that goes beyond the economics here, which again comes back to the dignity issue. If we want to help people, requiring that they prove that they are poor enough to get the help, I mean sometimes, all right. There's some kinds of aid that are always going to be poverty related, and that will make sense, but in general, you want to avoid having people ... If your goal is to make sure that everybody has something, then the easiest way to do that is just to make sure that everybody has it rather than say, "Well prove that you can't do it for yourself, and then we'll do it." That's demeaning, it's complicated, it's not something you wanna do unless it's really essential, and in many cases it really is not. - Tony made an interesting comment at the end of this rather complicated discussion, I think a quite exciting discussion of these 15 proposals, he asks himself the rhetorical question, "Is this a package?" and then he answers yes and no. On the one hand, no, that governments and policy makers should feel free to discard the elements that they don't care for. But on the other hand, there are interdependencies among them. Is your sense that if we think of this as a menu of options, that it still would be viable if we end up taking three or four or five out of the 15? Can they live independent of one another more or less? - Oh, I think so. I mean that's ... I'm not even too sure what the interdependencies are. I mean there are some that I know about. Not specifically the way Tony puts it, but to think in turn there's a substantial, a lot of people have been putting in a lot of hard thought on earned income tax credit and minimum wages, and the question is are those alternatives? Should we, as many in Congress used to say, do EITC and not minimum wages, and we now understand I think pretty well that they're complements, that the EITC makes it that a reasonably high minimum wage, among other things, makes sure that the EITC goes to where you want it to, that you're not ending up subsidizing employers, that you are in fact subsidizing the workers. There are certainly some ways, parts of it that work together as a package, but clearly not all 15. Maybe one look through it, there's some subgroups that are collections. - I don't have anything to add to that, I think that's exactly right. - One of the claims that comes up a lot when we talk about policies aimed at reducing inequality is that globalization is now such an overwhelming force that single countries hands to some extent are tied, that the transnational forces are great, and the constraints are too much. Tony is skeptical about that, of course, for many reasons. What do you think about this argument? - Globalization is way overrated as a constraint on what nations can do for several reasons. One is that even now, even with the world flapped and all of that, the bulk of what any economy does, certainly any large economy, but even small ones, is still producing goods and services for itself. That most goods, most employment is in non-tradable sectors. If you see these enormous trade numbers, that has to do often with essentially the same value added being counted multiple times, because we ship a component to one country, they do something to it, to which it goes on to another country, and so on. 70%, 80% maybe of employment is in non-traded sectors. There's actually no reason why you could not, for example, have stronger unions and higher wages in those sectors. If you ask what's the biggest employer in America right now, the answer is Walmart. Could Walmart be unionized without the jobs moving overseas? Well, yeah, you don't move retail trade over seas. So that's overrated. Then we also believe, there's good reason to believe, that the trade offs are pretty favorable even in the global economy. If we ask raising wages, yeah, that raises cost directly, it has on the other hand, probably some efficiency wage effects that raise productivity. There are probably ways to have, even in tradable sectors, to have a substantially higher wage sector than we now do while remaining internationally competitive. The world's biggest trade surplus right now is Germany, and German manufacturing labor costs are extremely high, offset by high quality goods and very good labor management relations. I'm not sure that we could all manage to do that, but it's kind of a lesson. If you think that the winds of global competition force us all to compete head-on with Vietnam, it just doesn't look that way. - I think that's right. (coughs) I don't know how to make it count of the number of jobs that are exposed to competition from low wage countries so that globalization is a real constraint, but in an economy in which 70 or 80% of all employment is in the service sector, it doesn't seem to me likely that we're that severely limited. By the way, wages in the, well the service sector is extraordinarily diverse, it includes Goldman Sachs, and it includes Walmart, but on the whole, raising wages in the service sector would not interfere with competition in tradable goods very much at all. I'd rather agree with Paul about that. Also, I wanna make the more fundamental point. The way to answer this question is to try, you don't know really how any very complicated set of policies works until you see how they work. The notion that you have to know the answer before you try a policy and move ... Which is, by the way, another reason for wanting to move toward limiting inequality one step at a time. See how it works, and then you will know, or have a better idea when to stop. - I can't resist adding also that something that we've certainly learned from LIS is that levels of inequality vary dramatically across countries, all of which are subject to globalization, many of which are direct neighbors of one another, trading partners and all kinds of things. I think Tony's argument that national policies matter are certainly persuasive. In a minute or two, in a few moments, I'm gonna turn to the question of achievability, and I might add that I've told Tony that one of the things we're gonna try to do today is have you talk a little about the transferability of these ideas to the U.S. context. But before I do that, I wanna ask you a question actually that he posed himself. In anticipation of us talking today, I asked him if he wanted to suggest a question, and he did that, he sent a question this morning. He noted that he gave a lecture last night at the London School of Economics based on the book, and a journalist in the audience made a very intriguing comment. The journalist remarked to Tony, as he put it, that in this book, Tony tries to bring together a range of departures, all of which are, excuse me, this has to do with the issue of Tony's implied critique of modern economics. So the journalist remarked that in the book, Tony tries to bring together a range of departures, all of which are now very much part of mainstream research, for example, heterogeneous agents, monopolistic competition a la Krugman, efficiency wages a la Solow, non-welfare as to welfare economics invoking sin and so forth. The journalist noted to Tony then when these are all taken together, that issues such as the trade off between equity and efficiency look quite different, and that brings Tony then to pose I guess a larger question. He said, "This leads to my question for Bob and Paul, "which is, how can inequality be brought back into "the center of economics?" - Well. I think that Tony is actually doing it in the right way. I don't think that it makes sense to tell the assemblage of graduate students in the U.S. "Inequality is the central, or a central question, "in economics, let's talk about inequality." There's an intellectual history to economics, and we're gonna follow some of those paths undoubtedly, and all those things that, that was very clever journalist by the way, I'm not sure we would have such comments here, but all of those items, the economics of heterogeneous agents, that makes sense in the history of economics because there's a history that did that once and then goes against it, and time to come back. The same thing about all the modern theories of the labor market, one way or another. I think that's the way to go. You want to correct deviations of mainstream economics from good sense and eventually that will help you understand the inequality issue better. But to tell everybody that we're now gonna start your program with inequality one, followed later by inequality two, does not sound to me like a successful way. - If you look at what's actually going on among younger economists, there are probably not a large number who are say, studying inequality, but we're studying issues that bear on inequality. Very much the latest Clark medalist, Fryer, is doing applied microeconomics, is very much is about the kinds of issues that are involved in the whole inequality discussion. In fact that's been true of several of, the Clark medal of course, it's given to an economist under 40, and it's the big prestige thing, it's the pre-Nobel, actually harder to get than the Nobel. - You're both recipients, if I'm correct? - Yeah. - Yeah. I was once 40. (chuckles) - So was I. Seems like a long time ago though, I guess even further in your case, so we go on. In fact, I've seen some complaints. Some people are saying we need to start give a few Clark medals that are not for applied microeconomics focused on labor markets, you know? (chuckles) Which has been mostly what we've been getting lately, which is telling you that we're not that far. Don't judge economics by what people who are now 60 did for their stuff. Judge it by what's happening now. Inequality is, I do of course, which I'm gonna port over to community now, the economics of the welfare state, which is clearly on these issues. It's not in the economics department, because it's a grab-bag. It's a bunch of different subjects. There are different disciplines there. I suspect that's always going to be true. It doesn't quite make sense as an economics course, but they're all topics that are being studied by economists, so I think that we're not in as much trouble as that suggests. - So there's hope for the future, it sounds like. - The message for Tony is that there is an internal logic to economics that's working itself out, and applying these things to inequality type issues is a good thing for this society, but it comes not necessarily, it doesn't have to come from inside economics, it comes from the world. - Let me turn our attention now to the question of achievability. I realize this is something we could probably discuss for hours, and we won't. But I wanna turn your eyes, turn our eyes, to the United States. As you know, the book was written, for those of you who've read it will know, most of the examples are about the United Kingdom, but many about the United States as well, and I think Tony's trying to make a case that would make sense in most high-income countries. He has noted, Tony has noted already that he's receiving the message that most of what he proposes is dead in water in the United States. He gave a talk in London last month, and he said he noted that the New Yorker said in its articles last month that, this is Tony speaking, "my proposals wouldn't work in the U.S., "but I don't believe that, "I don't believe they're off the wall." He's referring to a recent piece by Jill Lepore in the New Yorker in which she wrote about Tony's book, "In the Unites States, "most of his proposals are non-starters." I'd like to hear each of you reflect on that rather stark assessment. - Well. Yes, they are, many of them are non-starters now. They would not have been non-starters when Franklin Roosevelt was president, and there may come a time when they'll be starters. It's worth getting that stuff down and having it discussed on the chance that the evolution of the society and the political situation will move in the direction where they'll become, they'll have a little more appeal. Actually, they probably have some appeal now, it's the political system that is log jammed, and that may change. I think it's a mistake to be too short term in one's judgements about these things, and you cast your bread on the waters. - Firstly, if you ask which of these proposals could pass the current House of Representatives, or the current Congress, you gotta be kidding. But that's no way to think about it. Things change and issues can change radically. At the moment, the big changes in public opinion have been on social issues, but that I think is worth saying, that gay marriage was anathema to many voters just a decade ago, is now perfectly, is sweeping, because there is not much opposition left. If I try to take a really cosmic view at why is America different. It has been true that things that are within the discourse are achievable in European countries have been beyond the pail in the United States for a long time. It's pretty clear what that's about. Ultimately, the distinctiveness of U.S. political economy is pretty much about race, we know that. There's overwhelming evidence that that's what makes us different, but it's also of diminishing significance I would say, despite everything you see. Despite the fact that it's certainly of major significance, prejudice is on the decline, the society is itself becoming more ethnically diverse. People who thought that we'd have a solid liberal majority now because of the change in character of the population have been sorely disappointed, but I think there's lots of reasons to think that three presidential elections from now, the United States might be a very, very, different place politically, much more amenable to things that now seem completely off the table. - If you were to envision what might enter the realm of political feasibility in the United States in the next few presidencies, let's come back to this question about whether we're talking about shifting the market distribution or the post tax and transfer distribution. Where would we be more likely to see traction in the United States? - Let me quote some results of a political scientist, sociologist at Northwestern named Leslie McCall who has done some survey work on this. She finds that there is quite a fairly substantial consensus, even among self-identified Republicans, that the distribution of income is unfair. Unfair is a very key word here because for one reason or another, fairness still seems to be a virtue. There is this fairly good opinion that, especially incomes at the top, are too high. There's a little less consensus that incomes at the bottom are too low. Then she goes on to ask, should the government do anything about this, or what should the government do about this? The answer, generally, is no, the government shouldn't do anything about this. True amongst self-identified Republicans, Independents, and even a fairly substantial number of Democrats. This probably relates to a generalized mistrust of government, which we all think about, and may change. Then she asks, "Well who ought to do something about this?" Large numbers, majority of Republicans, Independents, and Democrats say business should do something about this. Well, I don't think business is going by itself going to do anything about it, but this suggests that there actually could be some viability for imposing changes in corporate governments and trying to either encourage or enforce changes in the way businesses make decisions, large businesses in particular, make decisions that effect inequality. I think there's some hope there. - Public opinion is quite strongly supportive of raising wages. Raising the minimum wage is overwhelming. I mean, it's hard to find any policy proposal that has as such a large super majority in favor of it, including Republicans, as raising the minimum wage, which that tells you something about our political system that it doesn't happen. But it's not a problem of public opinion. Even unionization, I've seem some results that say that again, even self-identified Republicans, if asked should workers have the right to form unions and seek higher wages, often say yes. These pre tax and transfer interventions, if anything, have a lot more public acceptability than the redistributive state afterwards. Then I think if, once you ... There are other results. You ask people do they approve of government benefits, government programs, many will say no. Then you ask, well are you a beneficiary of any such program yourself, they'll also say no. And these are people who are on social security and Medicare. One way to make these things, to get a program enacted, and after a few years, it becomes invisible and people think it's not a government program, it's just there. I think that will eventually happen actually with Obamacare. I don't think these things, the idea that the United States is fundamentally opposed to doing these, both pre market and post market, is wrong. - I think, Paul, you'll be happy when people's signs say, "Tell the government to keep their hands off my Obamacare." - Yes, yeah. - Right, except give them the way it's been done, it'll be, "Keep your hands off my kye-nick," "Keep your hands off my new jersey," but yes, exactly. - Speaking of public opinion though, Paul, I think I've heard you say and write, I think you've written about the Walmart case of raising wages, that it wasn't just tight labor markets at the bottom, that there really was some moral suasion going on, some sense of pressure from society, and given this big wave of discussion about inequality? - Yes, I think, it's not ... It's too narrow a view to think that unless we have actual legislation, nothing happens. It sure helps to have legislation, but a climate of public opinion, protests, among other things, what we think we know, what I think I know about labor markets is that wages are much less, again, pinned down. That there's a fairly, if you're a retail, a big box store or chain, that you have faced some real trade-offs. A low wage policy means you pay low wages, but it means high turnover, low productivity. It doesn't take a whole lot to push you into a Costco type policy of much higher wages. At least what arguably is happening with Walmart is that they are, a fairly a modest amount of external pressure combined with a slightly tightening labor market is enough to make a big difference in their wage policy. That's what we're looking for. - There was a story that played out in Massachusets a year ago, roughly a year ago, that's really very relevant here. There was a small chain of supermarkets. It was not a large chain, but the supermarkets were genuine supermarkets, competitive with the national chains of supermarkets. This chain of supermarkets was a classical high road employer. They paid high wages, they treated their employees well, and they made a profit. There was very low turnover, the people worked hard, they smiled at the customers, the customers smiled back and they came. The cousin of the CEO, who was a member of the board of directors, made a grab for the firm because he wanted to convert it to a real, efficient, tough-minded retailer. The two cousins were at odds on this. The bad cousin, the low wage cousin, the tough-minded cousin seemed to be winning. The workers went out on strike, the customers went out on strike. The customers were parading around the lot with signs saying, "We want Arthur," Arthur was the good cousin, and the stores couldn't do a damn thing. In the end, Arthur won. The bad cousin threw in the towel, the workers came back, the customers came back. Now this is Massachusets, and people are crazy in Massachusets and all that, but nevertheless, there is some of this and it can be made to work. - Although powerful unions and minimum wage laws help. So I mean, now clear, I mean, we think that, I pressure moral suasion can matter much more than economists like to think. I wouldn't mind having some real legislation behind it as well, but I come back to Tony's point that says this can be changed, that you do not want to be fatalistic and imagine that it's all determined by forces beyond our ability to manage, that there's lots and lots we can do. - In any case, inequality will be a theme in 2016, but how that will shape, we don't know. My question for you is, I think I'll start with you Bob, imagining that you were gonna enter the race, which would make many people happy. I'm gonna assume you're gonna enter on the Democratic side, maybe challenging Hillary and Bernie Sanders. What are you gonna tell the American people about inequality and how would you frame it today? Not 30 years from now, but today to try to make it palatable? - I have no originality in this kind of thing. You know, it's not what I normally do, and I would stick with what I imagine to be tried and true, and popular themes such as children. It's really a terrible thing to raise a generation of children who have no hope of, and who have legitimately no hope of getting anywhere, of making a success, who face infinitesimal probability of success. I'd push on the kids and I would push on fairness, which as I said, is most Americans respond very well and correctly to the notion of fairness. I would work on the, without suggesting that equality of opportunity is a fraud, I would try to get across the idea of real equality of opportunity and that it's not a trivial thing, it's not a matter of something that it says on paper. Opportunity is not on paper, opportunity is what the society offers you, and we have to do something about that. - So Paul, I don't know if you're gonna run against him, or run with him, but what are your, what would you say, though, today, in the current language that we think of today? - Almost exactly what Bob said. You talk about fairness, you talk about decent lives for American families, you talk about children having the opportunity to rise, opportunity for your children. The thing is, it's actually, this is already there. I mean, we know this is pretty much the language that Hillary Clinton is using, it's pretty much the language even of those Democrats we either are or her, or who some of her supporters wish would challenge her. Really on the Democratic side, it's all yes, you say it, but I don't trust that you mean it. The language is already there, and I don't think that's the problem. Actually there's quite remarkable unity on one side of the political isle on these issues, at least at this point, you know, have a Democrat, if a Democrat is elected, then when the question comes, "Okay, you say you're gonna raise "the minimum wage to where?" "You say you're gonna provide "more help to children, how much?" Then that's where it'll become, there'll be disputes, but I think that the general thrust, and this new view that says that wages are at least in part a political construct that can be moved, is again, widely accepted. So no, I mean it's not really, it's not gonna be a hard thing, and I'm not sure I could supply anything that isn't already there. - Neither of us is gonna get the nomination, but we might push Hillary Clinton a little bit. - But will you push her on the labor market, or on taxes, or both? Where would you push her? - I would try to do as little on the taxes, I think that that's working against the reflex. We're talking politics, now. That's a reflex that it's hard to beat. I would work on the things that we have been talking about. - I think high end taxes, there still is political as well as economic room to raise top tax rates, and to close loop holes. There is room for some ... I am led to believe by people I talk to that a Clinton administration, if such a thing is coming, would probably be seeking some expansion of aid focused on children. So the spending priorities would be on children, because we've actually, you know, in the form of Obamacare, we've already had a quite big policy focused on low-income wage earners, that's really who the big beneficiaries are there, and it's one that's financed by highly progressive taxes, so we've actually just had a significant strike against inequality, but the next step would be largely child oriented. I think the place where there's a lot of room, because it really hasn't been pushed it all, it hasn't been exploited, is on the labor market. - Yeah, I agree, except that I'm maybe a little more pessimistic about high end taxes. I can't help remembering that when the talk was about the estate tax, the press was full of family farms that had to be sold in order to get hold of the cash to pay the estate tax, and people swallow that sort of thing, whereas of course that's not what it's about. That's a hard nut to crack. It's worth taking a swipe at it, I'll agree. - One interesting just factoid, which no one seems to know, is that as best we could tell, the effective federal tax rate on the top 1% is back to just about what it was pre-Reagan. That reflects partly a reversal of the Bush tax cuts at the very top end, and it reflects the fact that actually, Obamacare is paid for with some significant surcharges on investment income. It may be hard to talk about it. Anything that smacks of punishing success is still going to be unappetizing. - Can you think of a good way to get capital gains taxed as ordinary income? - Well, talk about a revenue emergency or something, but no, I don't know. - What do you think about it? - But moving it up is a possibility. - Let me ask you if you have any final thoughts about the book, the transferability to the United States, inequality in economics, any final thoughts? - I mean I'd like to hope that we get a kind of one, two punch here, that we, if you like, last year was the year of "Hey, inequality's a really big thing," which is not news to LIS, is not news to a lot of us, but in the broader public it still apparently came as a revelation, and that maybe now we have the chance to say, "And there's a lot you can do about it." The fact that, of Tony's 15 proposals, the number that could pass the current Congress is minus three, and the number that are likely to pass in the next four years or so is not more than one or two, shouldn't change the fact that we actually have a set of pretty reasonable, you know, not, there are no technical obstacles to implementing a lot of this stuff, and that maybe moves us. - Well, I hope that's the case. You know, I'm older than you, Paul. It's gotta come sooner or I'm not gonna benefit from this. - [Paul] Yeah, I know. - Thank you very much, thank you to both of you. - [Paul] Thanks.
Info
Channel: The Graduate Center, CUNY
Views: 57,874
Rating: 4.7986112 out of 5
Keywords:
Id: DGmUtJkTaqc
Channel Id: undefined
Length: 61min 34sec (3694 seconds)
Published: Fri May 22 2015
Related Videos
Note
Please note that this website is currently a work in progress! Lots of interesting data and statistics to come.