How Seizing Russian Assets Will Change the Invasion of Ukraine

Video Statistics and Information

Video
Captions Word Cloud
Reddit Comments
Captions
It’s a $300 billion question. While everyone was distracted with  the $61 billion in Ukraine aid,  Congress was quietly making  a more intriguing play,  not in the Ukraine bill, not in the Israel bill,  and not in the Taiwan bill,  but rather in the nebulous omnibus fourth bill, that seemingly covered so many other things   that it was just easier for the  media to gloss over those details. Uhh, full disclosure, I’m guilty there too. Sorry! But the question in, uhh, question  is the seizure of roughly $300 billion in  Russian assets controlled by Western governments. It is a sensitive topic with  serious implications for the war. A super scientific poll of my viewers  shows a large majority supporting it. But whether you fall into that category or are a part of the minority,  and whether you call it a seizure, or a confiscation,  or proactive reparations, or a special banking operation,  both camps often miss out on some  of the subtleties of seizure—  or non-seizure. Welcome to the paradoxical world where  seizure will simultaneously cause  more global instability and be a force for more global stability. For those of us who have  survived that logical migraine,  on tap for today, we will cover  exactly what those frozen assets are,  what Congress’ bill does to  put the pile of cash into play,  the issues that will pop up with how  Russia might retaliate to such a seizure,  what this will do to the international  financial system as a whole,  why the West will get a hidden benefit by   downgrading the safety of  foreign investments there,  and we will save the best for last  with some lines on maps discussion  of how seizure undermines one of  the West’s key goals for the war. But we begin with the basics of the assets. Flashback to a decade ago,  when Russia first moved into and subsequently annexed Crimea. The West responded with  what, by current standards,   might be best described as light sanctions. Nevertheless, it was enough to cause  a notable financial crisis in Russia—  not enough to disrupt Putin’s  position in the Kremlin.  but enough to devalue the ruble from 36 to the  dollar on the date of annexation to 61 rubles at the end of 2014. Hence the adoption of what is now called the “Fortress Russia” strategy.  This was the Kremlin’s policy aimed  to build a rainy day fund of rubles  and more broadly insulate the Federation’s  economy from Western sanctions. The relevant consequence of  this for today is that the  Russian Central Bank built up $600 billion in savings by the time that  the invasion of Ukraine began in February 2022. Oddly, about half of the  money sat in Western accounts. That might seem strange given that the goal here  was to insulate Moscow from foreign coercion. Nevertheless, the Western financial  system is just too widespread,   and it is hard to distribute $600 billion  without parking quite a bit of it there. It may have been possible to move some  of it out on the eve of the invasion,  but remember that the Kremlin anticipated  that this would be a quick operation. Kyiv’s government would fall in short order,  and so there would not be time for a  Western sanctions campaign to matter. Side note: I know that what  makes this channel unique  is that I can tell you what peer-reviewed  international relations research tells us about  the conflicts going on in our world today. But in a bit of a reversal,  I actually turned this video into a peer-reviewed article. There is a link in the video  description for ungated access,  and it is part of a larger symposium  that I organized on the war.  Lots more free reading to do. But no tests later, I promise. Anyway, it is just really cool that a  video with almost 6 million views now   gets to become part of the peer-reviewed record. I am not sure this has ever  happened before in any field,  so thank all of you so much for giving me  the opportunity to do this kind of thing. Now, back to the Kremlin’s optimism,  we all found out in short  order that it was unwarranted. Consequently, the Western financial  system froze the $300 billion.  The money is still just sitting  there—none of it has been spent.  But Russia cannot access the funds. Not that we actually know where  the Kremlin would go to do that.  It is unclear exactly how much of it is  divided between the United States and Europe. The bill that we will talk about  in a moment speculates that the   United States has only four or five billion of it. The vast majority instead resides in Belgium.  France and Germany probably  have the bulk of the remainder. However, because any further action  taken on it would likely be coordinated   between the sides of the Atlantic, that  specific detail might not matter much. It is also unclear exactly how  much money that we are looking at.  It was $300 billion.  But the $300 billion is not just  sitting in somewhere in a vault. The funds are probably  accruing interest of some kind. Even a conservative investment  in a one year U.S.treasury bill  has about a 5% rate currently. Then again, as hard as this is to  remember, interest rates were close  to zero at the start of the war, so we are  not looking at $330 billion at this point. Regardless, it is something more than $300 billion,  and this interest will become important later. That takes us to what appears in the catch-all   bill that Congress passed in April. We  should start with what it literally says. The key distinction is that the  bill authorizes a transition  from freezing the assets to seizing the assets. So instead of Russia being  locked out of the accounts,  transfers of the money will  go into some other account.  Thus, Russia will never have the opportunity to  regain access the money because it will be gone. The bill creates the following timeline: over the first 90 days the Treasury has to figure   out exactly how much Russian money  the U.S. controls and where it is. Then after another 90 days,  the Treasury must report to  Congress on its findings. One month after that, the president may “seize,   confiscate, transfer, or vest” the money. That takes us to November.  Biden will still be president,  but within two months it could be Trump. Regardless, whoever is in charge  will then have the power to take the  Russian money and send it to Ukraine  to address damage resulting from the invasion. The bill also instructs that such  measures are to be done alongside the G7,  European Union, Australia,  and any other parties holding Russian funds. This puts a new sense of importance  on the upcoming G7 meeting,  to be held in Italy from June 13 to the 15. Now, this all sounds like upside  for the West on the surface.  The reality, though, is more complicated. Let’s cover the main concerns  and analyze just how problematic  they are or they are not. First up is tit-for-tat  issues from the Russian side. This has been the main thrust  of the Kremlin’s media response.  Basically, the United States takes things, and so Russia takes things back. The difference, of course, is a significant  asymmetry between the two parties. Investing Russian state assets  in the West made fiscal sense. In contrast, Western states haven’t exactly looked   at Russia as a great place to  store some dollars or Euros. Thus, Uncle Sam does not have a  frozen piggybank in Moscow that   the Kremlin can simply raid in response  to Washington raiding Russian assets. Consequently, the retaliatory threat is for Russia to seize the private assets of American, British,   or European citizens, according to  former president Dmitri Medvedev. The extra layer of complication  here is that when this happens,  the private American citizens getting raided  will undoubtedly sue the U.S. government. Yes, Washington did not directly  take their money. But there is   a clear causal pathway by which the  government’s actions led to the loss. Now, I am not a lawyer, so I do not care to  speculate on what will ultimately happen there. But I can tell you that you  might get an injunction to   freeze the seizure of the frozen Russian assets. Yep, that’s two layers of ice there. And if the courts rule in  favor of the private citizens,   Ukraine will not get any of the money  until those citizens are made whole. The whole thing turns into  a complicated reallocation   of assets without any benefit to anyone. The second category of problems is with future  investment and the Western financial system. The United States and, to a lesser degree, the European Union benefit from being   the de facto caretakers of the world economy. This has a whole bunch of intangible benefits. But   to briefly describe one, you get to borrow  money denominated in their own currencies. So, if you are the United States and you  somehow became desperate to pay back a loan,  you could always literally print  the money to satisfy the payment. In contrast, imagine that you are Argentina  and you want to borrow money  on the international market. Well, lenders will offer you dollars. So you take the money.  And when the loans come due, the lenders  expect to receive dollars in return. Consequently, if you do not  have those dollars on hand,  you will have to turn to the international   markets to buy dollars to pay off the debt. Actually, the fact that other  countries want to borrow in dollars  makes the dollar stronger and in turn enriches the United States. Combine that with the fact that U.S. treasuries are basically the safest investment that exist,  and you end up with a system  where the United States  can borrow money for ridiculously low rates. That’s a good thing when you  have a $34 trillion national debt  and, in 2023, ran a $1.7 trillion deficit. And, actually, access to cheap  credit is major reason why  these figures exist at all. As it relates to the seizure of Russian assets,   there is a major concern here  regarding other foreign governments. Ordinarily, they would want to store some money in   Western institutions. But they may  become worried that their assets could also be seized. Then they pull out of the U.S. treasuries market,  and suddenly interest rates  for Washington skyrocket. There is some concern that this  is already happening with China. Indeed, China held just over a trillion dollars in U.S. treasuries on the eve of the invasion. Now, it is down to $775 billion. To be clear, Beijing had started selling off  treasuries prior to war. This run began in 2018,  with $1.2 trillion being the local  maximum amount that China held. But the pace has accelerated since  the tanks spilled over the border. And, overall, this would lead  to a weakening of the dollar,  which is bad news for the U.S. economy. There is a good chance you have heard some  version of this argument before. But we   should spend some time examining why this is  not obviously a net negative for the West. Think of a spectrum of countries based  on how likely they are to do dodgy   things from the collective Western perspective. So one end you have Canada, where I was once threatened to be beaten up  and then his friend interjected that  they must do so politely. True story. And on the other end we have, say, North Korea. Everyone on this end does not think  twice in making Western investments. Everyone on the other end is already too  scared to hand over their financials. Let’s mark these for later. In between is where it matters. Those marginally over here will   be spooked by a Russian asset seizure and divest. Those marginally over here  will not like what is happening  But they were never likely to  draw the ire of the West anyway  and thus they stay in the system. So we have four total groups. The question beyond the paygrade  of us keyboard warriors is just how   far down the line the dividing point  between the two middle groups goes. If the split is up here,  then the precedent of seizure hardly  impacts the world economic structure. If the split is over here… well, that is the point where   Washington needs to worry that enough  of the world wants an alternative that China will then be greatly  incentivized to invest in a new system. And as a consequence, the West will  lose the more moderate coercive   lever of freezing assets the next  time something like this happens. But there is another factor at play here. All of the discussion is on  the precedent that seizure sets  and how it affects the  thought process of these guys. What receives less attention is the precedent  that would be set by not seizing the assets  and how it affects the  thought process of these guys. Think about those middling  countries that would stick   with the system despite registering  complains about U.S. overreach. We’ll use a Bizarro World version  of Ireland as a placeholder here,   who apparently is hellbent on dying  America’s precious waterways green. Before, when the opportunity to go rogue  arose, they did not see too much of a downside. Go green! But fast forward to the post-seizure  world, and there is a big fat  minus c cost in their calculations  because their assets too will be taken.  So they simply pass on going rogue in the  first place, and Americans can drink safely. Thus, the Western power  play loses coercive leverage  over this group but increases it over this group. I leave it to the experts to figure  out which has the greater net impact. Finally, we get to the main event  of the evening. Get excited, because it’s time for some lines on maps. Today’s  focus is the problem with imposing one-time costs. In other words,  a cost that a country can only suffer  one time and will not reset over time. Attacking a refinery is not  a one-time cost, for example,   because Russia can repair the damage, and  then Ukraine can impose that cost again. In contrast, the asset seizure  would be a one-time cost. As funny as it is to think about  the Kremlin calling in to buy more   treasury bills in the immediate  aftermath of the West’s seizure, that will not happen. The basic problem is as follows.  You have your standard white line to represent a hypothetical  expected territorial outcome   of the war if it fought to a military conclusion. And then you have Russia’s red line,  with the gap between the two  reflecting Russia’s costs of fighting. If you want Russia to withdraw to  at least the January 2022 borders   as part of the final settlement of this war,  then you need the red line pushed  back somewhere around here. That is either accomplished by  arming Ukraine to the teeth so   that the expected outcome of  war is very favorable to Kyiv or you impose so many costs on Russia that even a   favorable territorial outcome from Moscow’s  perspective is still a large net negative. Now, the problem with any one-time cost is that you   can only impose it … well … one time. And if Western   countries do that now, then they cannot do it again. Moreover, it is hard to imagine that it would be   possible to undo any seizing given that  the money will already be redispersed. Thus, once the seizure occurs,  it is no longer a cost of war.   It is just a fact of life that exists regardless  of Russia’s future war and peace decisions. But that means that Russia’s cost of  fighting until there is a military outcome  shrinks. And that means that the red line actually  goes further into Ukrainian territory. As a result, for the purposes  of pushing the red line back,  it is better to leverage the threat of seizure  than it is to actually do it—or at least not do it  until after the military outcome  of the war has been realized. That is the whole reason that  the West froze the assets in   the first place. They create bargaining leverage. Now, the cleavage between the West  and Ukraine here is interesting.  Ukraine is all for the seizure  despite the red line problem. The reason is because even if  the redline moves unfavorably,  Kyiv is adding a big fat $300 billion  to its war outcome regardless. In that sense, the asset transfer and  line shift are a zero-sum proposition   between Russia and Ukraine. One  exactly cancels out the other. In contrast, compared to Ukraine, the United  States places relatively more value on the war   ending in any fashion and therefore prefers  having the leverage rather than acting on it. That said, there are a few  ways around this problem. First, you could sell the seized assets, raise  money, and then buy more weapons for Ukraine. This narrows the location of the  redline because of the lost leverage,  but it shifts the expected  outcome line back the other way,   which pushes the red line along with it. The net effect is therefore nebulous. If the weapons are pivotal to the war,  for example, then it is possible that  the change in expected outcome more  than compensates for vanishing cost. Of course, you might want to  point out here that the House bill  calls for this money to go toward repairing  the damage from Russia’s invasion. But remember that money is fungible. That is, if more money suddenly starts   flowing to humanitarian ends, then coalitions partners  and the Ukrainian government suddenly have more money to spend  on things that go boom— and not just the finger guns. This is basically the sanctions problem, where carving out humanitarian exceptions  ends up funding the target’s military, but in reverse. Second, it is possible that war  counterintuitively becomes easier   to resolve when the costs for one party are lower. My self-respecting academic alter ego  has spent a lot of time researching that, and he tells the non-self-respecting version   of me that the conditions for this  happening are not present right now, so we might as well move on. If you really want to know how that  works, then we actually did an entire   video on the subject last year. But  that is superfluous for right now. The last workaround is less of a  solution and more of a compromise.  Rather than touch the $300 billion principal,  Western states will just  seize the interest accrued. And, again, with a T-bill generating about 5% annually right now,  even a very conservative investment strategy  still yields about $15 billion per year. The reason that this is not  actually a solution is because,   under a complete freeze, the interest  would go back into Russia’s account. Consequently, when interest funnels  back into the principal, every year   that the war continues, the effect on the red line is a small increase. $15 billion here.  $15 billion here. And $15 billion here. And actually, giving the  interest payments to Ukraine  means that the red line decreases  every year due to inflation. $300 billion just does not buy what it used to. But good news:  my books on the war still cost under  $300 billion. Power to the people. You can check the video description  for more information on them. And if you enjoyed this video, please like,   share, and subscribe, and I will  see you next time. Take care. By the way, this stock photo from  earlier is actually Biden getting briefed  on the Wagner rebellion from almost a year ago. It’s funny that the “what the flub” expression   on his face is virtually identical to  the one that we all had at the time.
Info
Channel: William Spaniel
Views: 452,783
Rating: undefined out of 5
Keywords:
Id: 19Hce4uef4k
Channel Id: undefined
Length: 21min 40sec (1300 seconds)
Published: Sat May 11 2024
Related Videos
Note
Please note that this website is currently a work in progress! Lots of interesting data and statistics to come.