Can Economics Help Us Save the Planet? Part 1 | Economics for People with Ha-Joon Chang

Video Statistics and Information

Video
Captions Word Cloud
Reddit Comments
Captions
(dramatic music) - You know arguably, climate change is the biggest challenge that the human race is facing, although there are lots of people who deny that it does even exist. Those people agree that this is happening, and this is happening mainly as a result of human activities, and we need to do something about it. (plane engine roaring) So a lot of people are wondering whether we need to change the economics system in order to address this issue. These are quotes from Naomi Klein, the Canadian, activist and author. The capitalist system or the free market system is at the root of the environmental problem. The response from the economics profession, dominated by neoclassical economists, is that actually the solution to the environmental problem is more markets, not less markets. Actually these economists have urged us to use markets more widely in terms of both setting the goals of environmental policy and creating the means of by managing the environment. Reducing pollution actually means that you are also going to forego the benefits of those activities that have generated pollution. This is a very reasonable point. Therefore these economists say, the optimal level of pollution is not zero. It doesn't means that you are going to completely forego the benefits of producing something, driving around. So they say, that you have to compare the cost of the damage that pollution creates and the benefits from the pollution generating activities, and compare them. The neoclassical approach tries to express all benefits and costs in monetary terms. So how much is it going to benefit people to produce this things? How much damage does it do in terms of ridding peoples health and sorts. They try to monetize all this, so that they compare them on a sort of objective basis. When trying to put monetary values on various costs and benefits involved a certain policy, neoclassical economists prefer to use a market price. If there's a market, you know. So a forest of trees used for Christmas trees is relatively simple to calculate. Of course, when it comes to environmental policy, typically the values of environmental assets are very complex. That for us to also provide other benefits. Sanctuary for an endangered species of birds, or it might give people a place for pleasant walks, and sports activities. This is among the specialists known as the amenity value of the forest. There is no market for endangered species of birds, and it becomes quite complicated. So suppose that the government is contemplating the introduction of this involuntary glacier about drinking water that will reduce the level of say arsenic in water, and you know it's going to save one life in one million per year. Then suppose that this country has a hundred million people, that's the population of Mexico, Ethiopia, you know so. So this means if you introduce this regulation, you're basically going to save 100 people. They'd be some cost that to doing this, so you need to compare that cost to the benefit but how do you value human life? And all the people at that point, give up, you can not value human life. But, many of my professional colleagues are undaunted by that, so they try to calculate it somehow, how markets value, human life. So one popular measure is to look at the wage differentials. What I mean is suppose that they are two jobs, but one job involves some risk. And another is risk free. Now the risky job would require paying higher wages to people, because people are not stupid, they know that their is a slight risk that of being killed in the job. So suppose that that probability is 1/10,000. So what economists due is to look at that and then say, what is the actual wage differential. If it's say, $900 per year, you will say, well people are worth willing to get paid $900 more for a 1/10,000 chance of being killed. Multiply $900 by 10,000, you will get $9 million dollars. So by using wage differentials, in the labor market economists have cleverly calculated, how people actually value their lives. I mean no one said, that I'm thinking human life is at $10 billion dollars, or $100 million dollars, but using a market prices, they have cleverly worked out how you can infer the kind of value that people put on what their own lives. Now this is a fictitious example, but it's not completely fictitious in the sense that $9 million is indeed the value upon what they call statistical life, used by US government agencies. When the US government agency decides on introducing tougher regulations on drinking water, or relaxing regulation on road safety they basically say one person is worth $9 million dollars. Well once again, we have a serious ethical problem here, because a lot of people will just refuse to value human life in monetary terms, period. But even when you accept that this is morally acceptable, there are lots of practical problems, because A, this suggests that when people choose these jobs that they do it with the full information. No, I mean usually they don't. No, I mean, yeah, people will vaguely know that there is a chance of getting killed, 1/10,000 chance, but do they really know it's 1/10,000 or that 1/9,000, 1/6,000, they really don't know. Also this practice assumes that wage is the only factor determining which job to take. Some work can be boring to the point of being soul destroying. So that there are these other dimensions of work, I mean that people consider when they choose jobs, so even though this neoclassical environmental economists, go out on limb to put monetary value even for human beings, even they admit that there are things where you simply can not use market prices to infer the value for. Environmental economists will recognize that environmental assets like forests provide ecosystem services like, stabilizing the soil, retaining water. So typically when you have a forest, when it rains, the water gets absorbed by the trees, and the forest as a whole, and moves slowly at the release so the risk of flooding is reduced. If you have just a de-forested area, the water just pours down, and actually creates flooding. And most relevantly for climate change, the trees absorb carbon dioxide. So it, there are these ecosystem services, some natural assets might have even cultural or symbolic values. Some forests might be considered a place of special significance for some group of indigenous people. Now how do you value these things? Economists though are people that don't easily give up, so what do they do? They do surveys. You can't just go to someone and say well that forest, in your area, how much would you value it for? No one has an idea like that, especially if the question becomes something like how much that do you think is a value of protecting this endangered species of bird that live in that forest. So that they have devised a rather clever questions like, if there's this charity, protecting this endangered species of bird, how much would you donate per year to this charity? Is it zero, is it $20, is it $40? So they have developed ways to kind of teasing out the people's real kind of monetary measurement through these surveys. Unfortunately, these surveys can be very unreliable, because these are totally hypothetical questions, you know those kind of charities may not even exist, yeah. And you might be asking people who have very different philosophy about their relationship with nature. And researchers have also found that very often when asked, these hypothetical questions, people often integrate them in their own way and re-frame the question as something like, how much money do you actually donate to charities protecting wild life. But that is a very different question from that very specific question about that particular endangered species of bird. So their are lots of problems with these surveys. But too go even deeper into the limitations of cost-benefit analysis, we can actually look at this very particular monetary value that you often hear in the debate on climate change. Now there's apparent consensus, that if we follow this path of business as usual, as it is called, basically do nothing to kind of control climate change. The world average temperature will rise by four degrees, and that will bring costs that is equivalent to our around 5% GDP per year. Is that a pretty widely accepted estimate, but when you actually pick this number apart and try to see how this has been constructed, you begin to see that a huge amount of assumptions and simplifications and omissions have gone into it. The number is very problematic. This is not to say, that we should never come up with these kind of numbers. When you are interpreting these numbers you really have to understand how these were made. And I sometimes joke, that numbers are like sausages. You don't know what went into them, you don't want to know what went into them, no. Numbers that are basically manufactured, even relatively simple things like rate of unemployment. These are highly manufactured numbers. Which is not to say that they are wrong, or fictitious, or misleading, necessarily, but you really need to know how this numbers have been created in order to judge whether that number is useful at least for the purpose that you are trying to use it for. There are a series problems illustrated by this 5% GDP number. And I've listed six of them. The first is that the issue of complexity. In estimating this 5% of GDP number, all of the things have been excluded, so people have pointed out that this estimate did not include the possibility of temperature rising above certain threshold, and starting the thawing of the Arctic permafrost. That area of frozen ground in the Arctic area, and some people argue that this will release a massive amount of methane gas, which is four times more powerful than carbon dioxide, in terms of it's impact on global warming, and they didn't include this. Others have pointed out, this estimate didn't take into account the fact that the rising sea level due to global warming, will destroy a lot of island nations, and cost economies. And how are you going to value that? No I mean, this rising sea level is a serious challenge for some of these islands states and I think one of the pacific island states basically have decided to buy up land in Australia, and move their country if the worst comes to worst. They'll get wiped out. People have pointed out that this estimate didn't include the cost from conflict resulting from large scale migration tens of thousands, hundreds of thousands of people might be moving to a neighboring country, what is the potential cost of that conflict. There is a very complex effects which have not been included in this estimation mainly because it's almost impossible to put the monetary value on these things. And then there is the issue of uncertainty. For some things, you know calculating problem is fairly easy, the insurance industry basically can exist because it's a rather easy to calculate the chance of someone with a particular ethnic background and lifestyle and occupation and someone dying in the next say 10 years, 20 years, or whatever. They have a pretty accurate estimation of the chance of some 18 year old guy who just bought a car, kind of having an accident. But when it comes to things like climate change, there's a huge uncertainty. Some would describe this as a caging uncertainty, because this is an uncertainty that does emphasize like cage you just can not estimate with any confidence the range of plausible probabilities. I think the person who put this idea most beautifully is Donald Rumsfeld, the former Defense Secretary of the United States. Of course he did it without realizing what he was doing, but he once said, there are known knowns, and there known unknowns, but then there are unknown unknowns, that's caging uncertainty, yeah. So there are things that we know that they exist, and can reasonably estimate the probabilities for. That's known knowns. Known unknowns, these are things that we know that is likely to happen, we can't quite estimate the probability but we at least know that they are possible. But with things like climate change, there are so many unknown unknowns. You don't even know that the problem exists not to speak of calculating the probability. And then so, when you have something like this, it is almost impossible to assign probabilities, to likely events. A, you don't really know what the likely events are. B, even if you know, it's almost impossible to put a probability on them. I mean for these things that are difficult of putting monetary value on, is that there really secondary. By nature things like climate change happen over a long period of time, you have to somehow find a way to decide whether say, cost of $100 dollars today, is bigger or smaller than benefit of $120 dollars twenty years later. Because, not unreasonably, all of the people argue that $100 dollar today, is more valuable than $100 dollar tomorrow. The main justification is that, especially when it comes to things like climate change. The world will be richer twenty, thirty, fifty years later, because we keep growing. The output keeps growing faster than the population, however low the rate is. Our future selves and our grandchildren they are going to be richer, so if we have to spend $100 million dollars, to do something about climate change, and if they get only $100 million dollar benefit, your future self and grand children then actually it's not worth it, because the cost is higher. Because that future $100 million dollars is not as valuable as today's $100 million dollars. So basically, what you do is you introduce this thing called discount rate, which is like interest rate, but into the future. And say, my discount rate is 3%, which means that $100 next year is only worth $97 dollars today. And then you keep using this rate to essentially calculate that something equivalent to compound interest rate that to know how much $100 will be worth, in 20 years, or 25 years, or 200 years. Now, discounting of course, is once again a sensible thing to do, but I mean it doesn't quite work for something like climate change with the long time horizon. First of all, with something like climate change, you don't even know that the world economy will be richer than today in the future. Because some people are predicting that when this climate change, that effectively will be so devastating, that actually the world economy might have trouble growing at the rate we have been growing. At some point, if the environmental challenges become too large, and the economy keeps shrinking, actually it becomes very difficult to justify discounting. But moreover, because that when you do this discounting, you do it in a compounding way, as the timeline gets longer the effects get magnified. And if the future timeline is very long, the effect of compounding will be huge. So to illustrate this point, you know the discount rate of for this environmental things are often set at 5%. Now if you use the 5% discount rate and calculated the value of World GDP which at the moment stands on 75.5 trillion. Say 200 years later, because of this compounding effect, it will be only equivalent to about $4.4 billion dollars. Which is 0.0058% of the original value, and equivalent to the GDP of Togo, the 155th largest economy of the 193 UN member countries. So basically it's nothing. Problem with climate change is that what the cost of that we need to pay to prevent it, mainly concentrated in the next 20-30 years. And the benefits that we see when we come in at the earliest of 40-50 years, and possibly 200 years into the future. So this is why many environmentalists argue that applying discounting to climate policy is a kind of discrimination against a future generation, simply because they are not here, and they will be here in 200 years, they don't count. This is a serious issue for something like climate change. I don't know calculating the value of a building or road in a particular area, probably some reasonable practice to adopt because the cost and benefit will be basically will be within the next 10, 20 years together. But for something like climate change, this is a big problem. What cost-benefit analysis does is actually not compatible with Pareto Criterion which is supposed to be at the foundation of neoclassical economics. So Pareto Criterion just to remind you says that you can not call a social change an improvement if it makes even one person worse off. What the economists do, when they do cost-benefit analysis, they aggregate all the costs and benefits without regard to the distribution of cost and benefits, and some will come up with a single value for the whole country, for community, even for the whole world, when it comes to climate change. There is no recognition that this is a completely incompatible with climate change. Because yes, that the net benefit might be positive, but it might mean making lots of people worse off. Having said that, you know the problem with cost-benefit analysis, not just to do with environmental policy but you have to recognize that, so that the distribution of consequences are completely ignored. And then there is the issue of the challenge of valuing human life. We already discussed how economists try to infer the value of a human life, by looking at labor market and wage differentials. However when it comes to climate change, the World Health Organization has predicted that a four degree warming would probably cost an extra half a million premature deaths every year. Because there will be more malaria, and more people will experience heat waves, or die of dehydration, and so on. How do you value the life of these people? Now the thing is, that if you use the wage differentials approach that we describe earlier, it will actually mean that you are going to value the life of people in poor countries much more lowly than you value the life of people in rich countries. Indeed, the entire governmental panel on climate change, IPPC has valued lives lost in rich countries due to climate change, at $1.5 million dollars. But that the lives in poor countries, only at about $100,000 dollars. It's basically because people in poor countries are a lot more willing to accept higher risk jobs at a slight wage differential, because they are desperate. These people saw a lot less willing to spend money on you know avoiding the risk of climate change. Because they have little money. So if you used that wage differential approach, the wage differential for a given risk will be lower in a poor country than that for the same risk in a rich country. So it, going back to that fictitious example earlier, in the US you might have to pay the guy $900 dollars more to make him do this job, that has the, 1/10,000 risk of death over risk free job. And in a developing country, this could be just $20. A lot of people get upset, this is morally unacceptable. You know, how can you say that some guy living in a rich country is 15x more worth than a guy that is living in a poor country. But whether we accept this difference as convincing depends on whether we think that the market prices are morally acceptable. Because that the lower value of life in poor countries is a consequence of using market prices. So that you have wage differential, in this country which is much lower, compared to that in a rich country, so that gives you low value of life, go back to Don Helder Camara quote, "When I give food to poor people, they call me a saint. "When I ask why they do not have enough to eat, "they call me a communist." That really shows how the market prices, are actually reflection of the underlying social order. If you think that you know poor people in poor countries are accepting this higher risk in their work, only because the say land is very unequally distributed when there's great barriers to social mobility, when there's oligarchy that prevents people's access to productive assets. Yeah, then you might say, well there's actually a wage differential which is much lower in a developing country is wrong. Because the underlying social order that produces that wage differential is wrong. And finally the issue of morality. From the Donald Trump camp which basically denies that is a caused by human activities, and therefore we can ignore it. We can't really do anything about it, to de-green's life like commented to address the cuts in emission, right now, right here, all of these people have moral concessions beyond GDP. And they are thinking about climate change because this is not just about you know do they have more money that 50 years later, will your grandchildren that have the less money than you do, it's about, first of all different peoples responsibilities for past emissions and cuts in future emissions, you know. You know 'cause a lot of developing countries are very upset that you know basically something like 70% of CO2 gas in the atmosphere was generated by the rich countries. And then know they say, what is done is done, you know you have to cut your future emissions. And then you know that understandably a lot of developing countries are upset about it, because it sounds like the rich countries are washing their hands off from their historical responsibilities. You know people are against actions for climate change, tend to argue that government intervention to transform the economy onto a low carbon path basically poses a great threat to economic freedom. The government doesn't have the right to tell us how to consume, how to produce. I mean, many environmentalists are not doing cost-benefit analysis, and say we should do this because x years later, we'll be better off we did this. They are moral thinking in terms of our obligation to the future generation, and our obligation to the planet. And you know how do you monetize this thing. If GDP was all that mattered, you could say that the second world war had not really effect on the world. No actually, by some estimates the second world war increased World GDP, so was it a good thing. Well no one will say that, because there was the Holocaust, there was the Atomic bomb in Japan, and yeah, I mean human suffering on a kind of cosmic scale throughout the world. So this poses a fundamental moral dilemma, there are so many ethical issues involved in, especially things like climate change. And we just have to know how to deal with this. I have discussed various technical, theoretical, and problems with cost-benefit analysis. This approach needs to be used in conjunction with other approaches, because it has some serious deficiencies. First of all, we need to use things like structure interviews or group discussion forums, in order to gain more nuance, understanding of what people want. Because I have already told you that when they do cost-benefit analysis economists sometimes resort to surveys, because there is no other way to find out how much people value this, how much they are willing to pay for, I don't know, flood defense or whatever. So what we need is to really keep people the opportunity to express their moral and political judgments through this discussion forums, and more in-depth structured interviews, because trying to force them to put monetary values on everything, is really distorting the picture. Okay, this way, you may not get one nice neat number, you know. But that's the nature of the world, it's messy, it's complex. Secondly, we need to take this issue of uncertainty very seriously when it comes to climate change especially. And people advocate this thing called the precautionary principle. This is the first kind of flag, in a major way in the 1992 Rio declaration on environmental development of the United Nations. The first idea is that we have to acknowledge the limits of our knowledge and accept that sometimes, that we just don't have enough information to come up with a reasonable probable estimation. Unfortunately, what happens is that when economists are supposed to do cost-benefit analysis for some government ministry or agency you know they are forced to invent these probabilities. When they have no real scientific basis, to come up with certain numbers, but since everything has to be put in monetary terms, and they need to produce a single number in the end, They have to invent this. The second idea is that some threats are fundamentally more serious, and should be treated differently. So things like climate change, is a problem in a class of its own. It's not like, I don't know, building a bypass, your I don't know, some market town in Cambridge. This is at the problem of by unique class and these problems need to be taken seriously and precautionary actions might have to be taken in relation to it, even if you don't have the full picture. Having seen how the cost-benefit analysis favored by the mainstream economist profession, the size of environmental goals and what the limitations of the approach are. We still need to discuss what kind of policy tools, and what kind of means are recommended to deal with climate problems and other environmental issues, and that will be the topic of the second part of this lecture, which will come later in the series.
Info
Channel: New Economic Thinking
Views: 25,306
Rating: undefined out of 5
Keywords: ha-joon chang, inet, institute for new economic thinking, matthew kulvicki, economics, economics for people
Id: Q8RIr4_YC3g
Channel Id: undefined
Length: 37min 17sec (2237 seconds)
Published: Tue Dec 10 2019
Related Videos
Note
Please note that this website is currently a work in progress! Lots of interesting data and statistics to come.