Thomas Piketty visits HLS to debate his book 'Capital in the Twenty-First Century'

Video Statistics and Information

Video
Captions Word Cloud
Reddit Comments

Great lecture, really interesting.

👍︎︎ 6 👤︎︎ u/digitalgokuhammer 📅︎︎ Apr 13 2015 🗫︎ replies
Captions
SVEN BECKERT: OK, good afternoon. Welcome. It's good to see so many of you here. My name is Sven Beckert, and I'm delighted to be able to welcome you here today in my role as the co-chair of the Program on the Study of Capitalism here at Harvard, and also as a faculty associate of the Center for European Studies. I would also like to welcome you in the name of Grzegorz Ekiert, who is the Director of the Center for European Studies, and Chris Desan, who's sitting right here, who is the co-director of the program on the study of capitalism. It is great to see so many of you here. I know many who would have liked to be here weren't able to join us. But I'm particularly honored to be able to welcome Professor Thomas Piketty as our speaker this afternoon. The Program on the History of Capitalism started more than 10 years ago here at Harvard. And when it started, an event like this seemed almost unimaginable. We had hoped to make more central matters of capitalism to debates in history and to bring other disciplines, including economics, into a broad discussion on the history and the present-day state of capitalism. And at first, such hope seemed truly futile. Our first seminars attracted very few students. And when I began to lecture on the history of capitalism, many well-meaning colleagues advised me that very few students would be interested in such an old-fashioned topic. Things turned out to be quite differently. And the study of capitalism has not only become extremely popular here at Harvard, but has become one of the most hotly debated topics in contemporary culture, with even Pope Francis and the Queen chiming in on such debates. But no one has made the problem of capitalism more intriguing, more intellectually alive, and more urgent than today's guest, Thomas Piketty. When in the late summer of 2013, Professor Piketty published his 800-page opus magnus in Paris, few would have predicted that it would become a global bestseller. After all, here was a book that was chock-full of tables and charts, dealing with decidedly yawn-inducing topics such as the history of taxation-- a book that, moreover, carried a decisively unsexy title-- namely Capital in the Twenty-First Century. And it was written in French. [LAUGHTER] Few would have predicted that 18 months later, the reading of that very book would at least lead one American CEO, Mark Bertolini of the Aetna Insurance Company, to raise the wages of his lowest paid workers, and that the press would come to compare its author to a rock star. Very few can claim that their writings have had such an immediate impact in the world. And it's a testament, not just to the brilliance of Professor Piketty's research but also to his ability to communicate that research to a wider public that Capital in the Twenty-First Century has fertilized political debate and has brought issues of the distributional effects of capitalism on the political agenda in many different parts of the world, including the United States. And of course, the book's success is also a sign of our own times. Thomas Piketty is professor of economics at the Paris School of Economics and at the Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales. He's the author of numerous articles and books focusing on the interplay between economic development and the distribution of income and wealth over the longue duree. With a degree from the Ecole Normale Superieur, he entered a PhD program at the Ecole des Hautes Etudes and the London School of Economics. And in 1993, he defended his doctorate dissertation on wealth redistribution-- a thesis that won the French Economic Association's prize for the best thesis of that year. Since then, he has taught at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in this fair city and worked as a researcher for the French National Center for Scientific Research. Most recently, he has led the creation of a massive database on world top incomes, which turned into the foundation for Capital in the Twenty-First Century. That book has now sold more than 1.5 million copies. And it has become the most widely reviewed and discussed book of last year, sometimes in confusingly contradictory manner, such as when the decisively anti-Marxist journal The Economist called Professor Piketty "the modern Marx," while self-identified Marxist David Harvey chided him for not being a Marxist at all. And another journal, The American Conservative, called him the anti-Marx. Beyond these confusions, Piketty's work has been of overwhelming importance to reigniting discussions on the distributional effects of capitalist development, the question of who gets what, and how that has changed over the past 200 years. In the course of providing powerful sets of data and interpreting them, Professor Piketty has created a new space for discussing inequality and possible political responses to that inequality. In some ways, one could argue that his most important contribution has been to allow us to think again about the future-- the future not as an inescapable new liberal faith that we must adjust to as best as we can, but instead as something that we can mold and shape politically. While his reading of the history of capitalism is often a dark one, his reading of the political possibilities of the human condition is deeply optimistic. Not only does he provide political ideas on how to address sharpening inequality, but he also gives us the mental space to allow us to think again about the possibilities for alternative futures. Economic outcomes, he tells us, are fundamentally political outcomes. And he encourages us to think not just about the run of necessity but also about the run of democratic possibility. Almost every commentator has justly emphasized Professor Piketty's contributions to the understanding of the long history of inequality. But the pages of his beautifully written book contain another contribution hiding in plain sight that is nearly as important and that I, as an historian, appreciate in particular. He has rescued thinking about the economy from the monopoly of economists. Professor Piketty reaches out to other disciplines, and especially to the discipline of history. And one can clearly see the influence of such towering voices as Fernand Braudel and Marc Bloch. His is not a past of immutable laws of development but a past that is political, a past that is contingent, and a past that is embedded in cultural and social change. The Trente Glorieuses, for example, are not the result of immutable economic loss but the result of a confluence of political factors and events. And thus, Professor Piketty's work is grounds for optimism for yet another reason-- that we might be able to reignite a discussion on the economy, its past and its future, by bringing in the voice of historians, anthropologists, sociologists, and many others. Without much further ado, I would like to open the proceedings. Professor Piketty will speak for about 45 minutes. And he will then be followed by three very short, five-minute responses from members of the Harvard faculty before we open up the discussion to the floor. And let me just introduce quickly these three commentators before we move on. David Kennedy, who will respond first, is the Hudson Professor of law and Faculty Director of the Institute for Global Law and Policy at Harvard Law School, where he teaches on international law, international economic policy, and also legal theory. He has published widely on international law and just recently published Global Governance: New Thinking About Law and Policy. He's also the mastermind behind the Institute for Global Law and Policy, a project that brings together people across many disciplines to think in new ways about globalization, its power, and its challenges. Stephen Marglin, who will speak next, holds the Barker Chair in the Department of Economics at Harvard University. His recent work focuses on the foundational assumptions of economics and how these assumptions make community invisible to economists. This work reflected in this book The Dismal Science: How Thinking Like an Economist Undermines Community attempts to counter the aid and comfort these assumptions give to those who would construct the world in the image of economics-- ultimately a world without community. And last but not least, you will hear from Christine Desan, who's not only the co-sponsor of the Program on the History of Capitalism here at Harvard but also, perhaps even mainly, the Gottlieb Professor of Law at Harvard Law School. Her work centers on the institutional underpinnings of capitalism so that we can open them up to revision. She in particular explores the history of money as a legal and political project, and just published Making Money: Coin Currency and the Coming of Capitalism, a book that decodes the monetary architecture of capitalism. Thank you again for joining us. And thank you again, Professor Piketty, being with us today. Professor Piketty. [APPLAUSE] THOMAS PIKETTY: Thank you. Thank you, Sven. And I'm very glad to be here. I'm sorry that my English sounds a lot like French, but I hope you can understand me. I'm very glad to be here in Cambridge. And my book first came out in French, and it came out in English shortly after that. And now it has been translated in many languages. And out of about 1.5 million copies, I guess there's about 500,000 in the English language, 500,000 in European language-- French, Italian, and German-- and about the same, 500,000 in Asia-- in Japanese and Chinese. But I think the English version played a particular role. And I would really like to pay tribute to Arthur Goldhammer, who is right there in the first rank. [APPLAUSE] There's no way I could have written such beautiful English and such a beautiful book in English. You can see my English. And I'm not particularly good with foreign language. I do what I can. And my written French is much, much better than my written English. And there's no way I could have referred to the literature or to express myself with the same clarity which Art was able to do by translating my book into English. So I think this is has been really-- it's more than a translator. I guess a translation is always more than translation. And of course, there's no [? czar ?] language for which I am able to check the translation was so good. So thanks a lot, Art. So let me-- in this presentation, I'm going to try to present some of the results of the book and reflect about some of the debate, also, that this book has stimulated over the past year or so. So let me first say very quickly that this book comes from a very collective project of data collection. So I am trying, in this book, to put the study of the distribution back at the center of political economy and of the social sciences more generally. But primarily what I have been doing in my research is to collect a lot of historical data on income and wealth. And this is something that I could never have done without several dozens of co-authors from over 20 countries. So in particular, I started collecting data on income and wealth in France about 15 years ago. And then I was very fortunate to meet Tony Atkinson, Emmanuel Saez, Gilles Postel-Vinay, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Facundo Alvarado, Gabriel Zucman, and many others which-- I cannot quote everybody here. But it's clear that there is no way I would have been able to collect all these data by myself. And this is an ongoing process. And so the book is just photography of the kind of historical material we had at one point in time. But there will be more data collection and more historical material available in the future. So thanks to this data collection, we know a little bit more than what we used to, but we still know too little. And in particular, there's absolutely no problem in my mind if people disagree with some of the historical interpretations that I give or the patterns that I find. We are in the social sciences. There are different ways to interpret historical evolution. And so the objective of the book is not to say, OK, this is the one way, the one law to interpret history. Of course when you look at the evolution of income and wealth distribution over more than 20 countries across three centuries, there cannot be just one law or one principle. There are many different institutions, policies, social control, political processes that play a role. And I'm trying to illuminate some of them in the book. But this is just the beginning. And there is a lot more to do in this area. So in this presentation, and I'm going to present some results, mostly from part two and three in the book so as to give you a sense of the material. If you go to this website, you will find all the graphs and series. And you will have a better sense of what material is included in the book. So in this presentation, I'm going to focus on these three points. I will start with the first point, which is about the long-run dynamics of income inequality. And then I will move to wealth. And to a large extent, what my book is trying to do is to shift the attention from the issue of income distribution to the issue of wealth and property concentration. But I will start with income inequality. I will show you the number of results about the long-run dynamics of income inequality. And some of the main conclusions will be the end of the Kuznets Curve, the end of universal law, and the idea that country-specific institutions and policy are absolutely critical if you want to understand the long-run evolution of income inequality in the various countries. Then point two will be about what I call the return of patrimonial or wealth-based societies, particularly in Europe and Japan, where wealth-income ratios seem to be returning to very high levels in those countries. And I will stress also the metamorphosis of capital, the transformation of the different forms of property, which raise new challenges for the future. And the third point will be about the future of wealth concentration and concentration of property. And I will argue that one of the important forces-- certainly not the only one, but one of the important forces-- for understanding the future of wealth concentration is the gap between R and G, where R is the net of tax rate of return, particularly for a large wealth portfolio, and G is the growth rate. And to the extent that this will be higher in the future than what it was in the past, this might contribute to rising inequality. So let me start with the first point about the long-run dynamics of income inequality. So a big part of the data on income inequality that I present in the book comes from this database, the World Income Database. So you can't see the colors very well, but let me just say that the countries in red-- well, say in black-- are already in the database. And the countries in blue, like Brazil or Algeria, are about to enter the database. So what it means to be in the database is that we try to collect all the historical data on income that we have for a given country. So usually, the only source of information on income comes from the income tax itself. So it's important to realize-- but you all know this-- that taxation is more than taxation. Taxation is also a way to produce information. It's a way to produce legal categories and statistical categories so that society can also accumulate knowledge about itself. And so when you don't have an income tax-- the income tax was created in 1913 in the United States, in 1914 in France, a little bit earlier in Japan and Germany, where it was created around 1880, 1890. In India, it was introduced in 1922 by the British colonizer. So almost everywhere between 1900 and 1920, you have the creation of the modern income tax. And this creates, also, a source of information about income. Of course, that's not a perfect source of information. But it's better than no information at all. So in the 19th century, you don't have an income tax in most countries. So, like in France, you have the contribution des portes et fenetres, the contribution on the number of doors and windows. So you have all sorts of beautiful statistics on the number of doors and windows by department, which is quite interesting, by the way. And this is an historical data source that is certainly underused. But it's less interesting, in a way, than income. And so this is true for income. This is also true for wealth-- the taxation of wealth, in particular the taxation of inherited wealth, transmission of wealth at a time of inheritance. It's also a way to register property and to register wealth and to produce information about wealth. So the taxation of wealth, in particular of inheritance, as much older than the taxation of income, because registering property is very important to organized society in general. So you have registration of property in very ancient societies. And in particular, in France, with the French Revolution, you have the introduction of an inheritance tax that was pretty universal for the time. And this is why we can go back and with fellow historians, Postel-Vinay and Rosenthal, to the French archives, to the late 18th century to study the distribution of wealth in France starting in the late 18th century. Now, for income we cannot do this, but we can start at least around 1900, 1910. And so we can study the evolution of income inequality. I should mention that one of the very positive impacts for me of the publication and the success of the book is that it allowed us to access historical fiscal data and current fiscal files in new countries where government were not so open. So now in Brazil, in Mexico should be in blue on the map. In Taiwan and Korea, in Chile, we are accessing the historical income data which we could not access before. And so there are more countries in particular that we try to cover in the emerging world-- in Latin America, in Asia, also in Africa. We put a lot of energy on trying to use data from Africa. So the countries that are not covered in the book, it's not that we don't want to cover them. It's just that sometimes we had no access to the historical sources. And we now have more access to them. So let me show you some examples of what we find in this database. So let me present three facts about inequality in the long run-- one about income inequality. And then I will show you about wealth inequality and finally about wealth income ratio. And if you want to have a short summary-- the book is very long, and I should apologize for that. So if you want to have-- the good thing about science, about real science and real scientific people, is that they want short articles. So when we had to publish this paper with my friend and colleague Emmanuel Saez in Science last year, this had to be five pages long. So if you want a five-page summary, you can read the Science article called "Inequality in the Long Run," where you will have these three facts about inequality in the long run that are exposed in a very condensed manner. But I think you will lose some of it. In particular, you will lose the beautiful translation of Art. This will just be my English, so that's less interesting. But at least the basic facts will be presented in a very condensed manner. So fact number one-- fact number one is the following. In 1900, 1910, income inequality was higher in Europe than in the United States, whereas in 2000, 2010, it is a lot higher in the United States. So that's an interesting reversal of inequality in the long run, because the way I will interpret this is that changing institution, changing policies can make a difference. So it's not that some countries are always more unequal than others. It depends how you organize yourself in a country. There are different ways to organize capitalism. And there are different levels of inequality that go with it. So let me show you one simple graph. So this is the share of income going to the top 10%. So you have Europe, the US. So Europe, as you know, is a complicated continent. But here I am going to simplify things. And so what I mean by Europe here is the GDP-weighted average of Germany, France, Britain, Italy, Sweden. So it's not quite Europe, but it's a big part of Western Europe, at least. And the general evolutions are very similar for the different-- at least continental European countries. So let's call it Europe for to simplify. And as you can see, in fact in all European countries, income inequality was higher in 1900, 1910 than in the US. Whereas today, you can see-- so there was a big decline in inequality following World War I and particularly World War II, the Great Depression. And in the 1950s, this is what Kuznets finds in his famous study. Inequality is less in the 1950s than in 1910. So all what we've did in this research is to extend the work of Kuznets to many more years in many more countries. And as you can see, this changes a lot the perspective, because in the '50s, you could have this optimistic view of decline and then stabilization of inequality at a lower level. Now in 2010, it's a very different story, because you've had this very big increase of the share of total income going to the top 10%, which in the US went from about one-third to about almost one-half. So when you go from one-third to one-half of total income going to the top 10, this is not just an issue of a few individuals getting very rich at the top, which after all, nobody cares if it was just a few individuals. But here we are talking about significant macroeconomic share in total income. So here, it looks very smooth, because I look at decennial averages, so everything looks very smooth. And that's convenient in order to focus on the long-run pattern. If you look at annual series for the US, you can see that is much less smooth. In particular, if you take into-- so this is the same curve as before, except that I only show you the US. And I look at annual series rather than decennial averages. And you can see, in particular because of capital gains, that the stock market cycle has a strong impact on inequality. So you can see in the US, in 2007, you have a very high point in inequality. Now in 2008 and '09, this is clearly not a good time to exercise your capital gains and not to cash a big bonus. So you have a decline in inequality. But then in 2012, you are even higher than 2007. So in 2012, you have 51% going to the top. In 2013, it seems to be a little bit lower. Anyway, you have short-run variations, but if you take the long run picture, it's pretty clear that you have a spectacular increase in the share of total income going to the top 10%. So if you just take the decennial averages and you compare to Europe, I think you can see how big the difference between these two different groups of rich countries-- the US on the one hand, and European countries on the other hand-- is. If you were to put Japan on the graph, this is what you would have. So Japan would be in between Europe and the US, closer to Europe in many ways. So it's interesting to put US and Europe and Japan, because these are like the three parts of the rich world. And you can see that they have different experience. So that's important, because sometimes people want to explain rising inequality just by talking about globalization. And the story will be, OK, you have globalization. You have China entering in the world labor market. Therefore, this is putting a strong pressure on the wages of low-skill workers, and this is what creates rising inequality. And I'm not saying this is not important. But I'm just saying that if this was the only explanation, then you should have the same rising inequality everywhere, because globalization happened not only in the US, but also in Japan and Europe. So sometimes we have debates which are very much self-centered in the US, but also in Europe or in Japan. But I think it's important to look at other countries' experience, and to realize that globalization is important. But then there are different institutions, different policies, that help to organize globalization and to allow broader groups of the population to benefit from globalization. So what are these policies that can make a difference? Well, I tried to analyze them in the book. But let me summarize very quickly. So the rising US inequality in the recent decade is mostly due to rising inequality of labor income. Also, rising concentration of capital income and wealth is starting to bump in at the end of the period. And a recent study by Saez and Zucman emphasizes this. But most of the action so far comes from rising inequality of labor income. This is due to a mixture of reasons-- changing supply and demand for skills, rise between education and technology. Globalization certainly is part of the story. But I think there's more than that. You need to have a story where you have more unequal access to skills in the US than in Europe or Japan. So maybe raising tuition, insufficient public investment in education, that can explain why you have higher inequality in skill acquisition and access to education in the US than in the rest of the rich world. Unprecedented rise of top managerial compensation in the US-- why did it happen so much in the US? There are complicated, changing social norms and also changing incentives and changing corporate governance. I tend to believe, on the basis of my research with Emmanuel Saez and Stefanie Stantcheva, that the very cut in top income tax rate that have occurred in the US since the '70s, '80s, have also played a role and have transformed the incentives for very top managers to try to bargain very aggressively, and try to get very high pay increase, which are often difficult to explain on the basis of observed performance or observed productivity, and have more to do with the ability sometimes to put the right people in the right compensation committee in order to get pay increase. Fall in minimum wage in the US also played, clearly, a role. So I don't ask you to agree with the exact importance of each explanation. But I think we can all agree about the fact that education policy, corporate governance, fiscal policy, labor market policy-- all these different institutions matter and explain why you can have different rising inequality in these different countries. Just let me show you the example of the minimum wage. So this is a graph that is taken from my book. So this is the real value of the minimum wage in France and the US. So you see that in the '50s, '60s, the minimum wage used to be a lot higher in the US than in France, whereas today it is a lot smaller. So some people in France will say that it is too high in France, which I'm not going comment on this. It's a reasonable discussion. But it is certainly too low in the US. Or at least-- in the US right now, the federal minimum wage is $7.20 or $7.30 per hour. It used to be $10 in the late 1960s. So it's quite unusual. So this is expressed in dollars of today, in 2013 dollars. So the purchasing power of the federal minimum wage in the US is today less than what it was in the 1960s at a time when there was no more unemployment than today. So it's quite unusual in a country to have a decline in the real value of the minimum wage over a 50-year period. And clearly this change in labor market institutions, change in collective bargaining, the role of unions also played a big role in the evolution of inequality. Let me show you another graph regarding education. So this is taken from a very interesting research by Raj Chetty, who teaches at Harvard Economic Department, with Emmanuel Saez, who is at Berkeley. So you have-- on the lower horizontal axis, you have the parental income rank. So if you have 10, it means that you are in the bottom 10% of the family distribution of income in the US, and 90, you are in the top 10%. And this is your percentage attending college at 18, 21. So you get an almost perfect straight line. And you go basically from 0% to 100%. So if your parents are poor in this country, your probability to access higher education is a little more than 20%. And then if your parents are in the top 10%, it's 90%. So you don't go from 0 to 100, but you go from 20% to 90%, which is almost as spectacular. I find this graph very striking. So this means that you have a theoretical discourse about meritocracy, equal opportunity, access to higher education, and you have the reality. And the reality is a bit frightening. And I also-- I'm not saying it's perfectly equal in other countries. I think there's a lot of hypocrisy and a lot of inequality in access to higher education everywhere. Certainly in my country, in France, there is sometimes a lot of hypocrisy in the ability of public institutions to invest three times more in very elitist schools than in normal schools. But there is evidence that inequality in access to higher education is even higher in the US than in Europe or in Japan. And I give evidence for this in the book. So anyway, this is just to illustrate that education policy, access to education, is very important, together with the minimum wage, together with progressive taxation. So it's a whole set of institutional policies that matter. Now let me move to the second part of my lecture, which is about the return of patrimonial society. So, so far I have focused mostly on inequality of income and particular labor income. Now I want to move more to wealth and capital, which is the main subject of the book. So of course, inequality and wealth and capital ownership is partly determined by inequality of labor income, because if you have more unequal labor incomes, then you have more unequal resources to save and accumulate wealth and become owners of large pieces of property. But the inequality of wealth is a more complicated object than the inequality of labor income because it also involves inheritance. It involves natural resources, which have been saved by no one. And the concentration of property is always a lot higher than the concentration of labor income, as I'm going to show you in a minute. So I'm going to make first a point. Point number two of my presentation will be about the return of what I call patrimonial or wealth-based society, particularly in Europe and Japan, where I will show you that wealth income ratio seems to be returning to very high levels in these countries. So what's particular in Europe and Japan is that you have very low population growth-- and indeed, in fact, negative population growth in Japan or in some European countries. And that's a very big difference with the US. And the basic intuition is that in a slow-growth society, wealth accumulation in the past can naturally become very important. And in the very long run, this can be relevant for the entire world, to the extent that population growth will stop everywhere at some point. So of course, if you have a lot of migration, you can keep growing. And I know that this is a country where immigration is important. In particular, universities would like all the rest of the planet to come here. But you know, if we are all in the US, that will not solve the problem in the long run. You still have-- population growth will depend on fertility. The projections we have so far is that population growth in the long run is going to be smaller than what it was in the past, and possibly close to zero. So to the extent that there will be a slow-down for other parts of the planet than just Europe and Japan, this rise of wealth income ratio and this return of what I call a patrimonial society will be relevant in more countries. Now this is not bad in itself, but this raises new challenges. And in particular, I will argue that the metamorphosis of capital assets call for new forms of regulations, of property regulations, and that these will be very important issues in the future. And then I will move to point number three. So regarding point number two, let me first stress that wealth inequality is always a lot higher than income inequality. So let me show you-- let me first describe two important facts. So remember, fact number one was that income inequality is now higher in the US than in Europe. Fact number two is that wealth inequality is always a lot higher than income inequality and that it is also now higher in the US than Europe. But fact number three, wealth inequality is still less extreme today than what it was a century ago in Europe, where it was really very extreme, in spite of the fact that the total capitalization of private wealth relative to national income has now recovered from the World War shocks. So it's important to distinguish between inequality on the one hand and total quantity, or total capitalization of wealth-- which is not quite the same thing-- on the other hand. So the fact that you have a very high total capitalization of private wealth is not necessary bad if you have a large middle class which also would be part of total wealth. So it's important to distinguish inequality on the one hand and the wealth income ratio on the other hand. So if we look at inequality-- so first look at the orders of magnitude. Remember, for income inequality, the top 10% share was between one-third and one-half. It used to be one-third in the US. It is now closer to one-half. Now, wealth inequality, it's always more than one-half. It goes between 60% to 90% in Europe before World War I. So wealth is a lot more concentrated than income. For many people, the bottom 50% share in wealth is always less than 5%. So there's a very large group in the population for whom the very notion of wealth or capital ownership is quite abstract. And many people just have a little savings in their accounts, or they have a mortgage that is almost as big as their real estate property, so their net wealth is really quite small. So whatever does not belong to the top 10% typically belongs to the middle 40%-- what I called in my book the patrimonial middle class, the people who are not in the bottom half, and who are not in the top 10%. And so whatever does not belong to the top 10% on this graph belongs to this middle 40. So this means that when Europe goes from 90% of wealth for the top 10 prior to World War I to about 60% today, in between you have 30% of national wealth which used to belong to the top 10 which now belongs to the middle 40. And this is this rise of a patrimonial middle class, which I describe in my book as probably the most important transformation in the long run, because even though the middle class still has less wealth than the rich-- in spite of the fact that they are four times more numerous-- it's still significant to own 30% of total wealth rather than 5% or 10%. This makes a big difference. Now, in recent decades, the share going to the top has started to increase again, which means that the share going to the middle class has started to decline. And one issue is to understand why. First, we're going to try to understand how the total value of wealth has changed. Now, what is striking-- so this is a different evolution. This is a wealth income ratio. And what's striking is that for wealth income ratio, Europe is actually above the US. So in Europe, there is less inequality of wealth than the US, but the total value of wealth relative to national income is higher. So that's why it's important to distinguish these two dimensions, because they don't need to move together. And so if you want to understand this big evolution of the wealth to income ratio, you can also decompose between different countries. So these are three European countries-- Germany, France, UK. You can see that everywhere you have a very high ratio of wealth to income prior to World War I. So of course you have a lot of destruction and also lack of investment between 1910 and 1950. Also a lot of private wealth was either nationalized after World War II or its private value was reduced by new sets of institutions and policies, including rent control for housing values, so that the private value of wealth in 1950 is extremely small by historical standards. And then it has started to increase again in the past half century and is now not quite as large as what it used to be in the 19th century. But it's getting closer. Now, how can we understand this big evolution? So the first point is that there's nothing bad with high wealth to income ratio. And to a large extent, it comes from a natural evolution with post-war reconstruction and the slow-down of growth. As I mentioned before, when you have a slow-down of growth in recent decades, you tend to accumulate more wealth relative to income. That's partly due to aging. And this is not necessary bad in itself. Now, the problem is that this creates new policy challenges in terms of financial regulation, real estate bubbles, return of inheritance, which is now for the new generation very important in Europe and also in Japan. And in order to analyze these issues, probably the most important message of this presentation is that I really try in my book to develop a multi-dimensional approach to the history of capital and property relations. When you do this big addition and compute the total value of all assets, you are really doing something very abstract. And the reason why my book is relatively long is because I actually try to analyze in a separate way each separate assets-- from land to business assets, to foreign assets, real estate, public debt, immaterial capital. And all these different kinds of property give rise to different institutional challenges, to different negotiation between owners of capital and those who mostly own their labor. And they really need to be analyzed separately if we want to understand them properly. And it's more than just making the big addition. So let me take a couple of examples to illustrate this point. First, if you look in the very long run-- so this is a decomposition of the structure of property in the United Kingdom. So you don't see the color very well, but let me just say that the bottom part in the 18th century is agricultural land. So you can see that at the beginning of the period, agricultural land is a very big part of wealth. The middle part is housing, which was less important in the 18th century but is now very important, partly due to a very high price for housing, maybe reflecting partly a bubble, but also the fact that many people want to live in the same place. And there could be something structural in these very high housing prices. The third part is also domestic capital, which is basically business assets, which becomes very important with the Industrial Revolution. And you have a little white part, which is very important on the eve of World War I, which is net foreign capital. So this is what Britain owned in the rest of the world. And you can see that this is very significant. You have almost two years of national income. Almost one-third of everything the Brits own in 1910 is they own part of the rest of the world. And of course, that's related to their colonial empire. In France, there's a smaller colonial empire, but still, it's quite a significant. It's more than one year of national income in foreign assets. And now this disappears entirely in France and Britain during the 20th century. Partly it's decolonization. But most of it is really World War I and World War II, where, to finance the war, to pay for the war, many of the rich French and Brits have to sell their foreign assets, buy some public bonds to their government. And then their public bonds will be inflated away after 1945, so that in the end, they don't own much after that. So that's a big part of the process. And if you just look at the big addition and you don't look separately at these different assets, you cannot really understand the whole thing. So what's striking in the long run is that you have metamorphosis of capital in the sense that agricultural land is not really playing a big role today. But the total the value of assets is getting similar, like in Britain in 2010 than in the 19th or 18th century, but with a very different form of assets. Let me mention also that if you look at annual series for more countries-- so here you have the same private wealth to national income ratio in more countries-- you can see the Japanese bubble in 1990. And generally speaking, what you can see is that bubbles on price of real estate and very sharp movement and price of other capital assets play a big role. So the history of capital is never quiet. It is full of crisis. It is full of volatility, because it's difficult to put a price of assets, also. Putting a price on real estate, or putting a price on the stock market-- some people do this for business, and that's complicated. And so you have all these big variations. If you look at the-- so this is the Spanish bubble over there, which is even bigger than the Japanese bubble. You can see that in Spain in 2007, the total market value of private wealth relative to national income was eight years of national income-- even more than in Japan, where it was seven years of national income in 1990. So this creates new challenges in terms of financial regulation. In 1970, the ratio of private wealth to national income was only two to three years-- so these are the top eight or top nine developed economies in the world. So everywhere it between two and three and a half years. Whereas today, it's between four and seven or eight years. So of course, if you make a 10% mistake on the price of your real estate in Spain or Japan, when you have a ratio of six or seven years of GDP in private wealth, this is a mistake that can have very big consequences, much bigger than when it's a ratio of two or three. So this creates new policy challenges. Let me also mention that a significant part of the increase in private wealth to GDP ratio is also a transfer from public to private capital. So you have privatization of public assets. And you have an increase in public debt. So public capital-- so you can see-- well, again, you don't see the color very well. But I just want to mention one example. Look at Italy. Italy is the bottom point for public capital and actually is the top point for private capital. So bottom point for public capital-- look, Italy is negative for public capital. What does this mean? This means that even if the Italian government were selling all the public assets, all the public buildings, schools, hospitals, financial assets-- they don't have much, but assume they sell everything-- that will not be enough to repay the public debt. They will still have about minus 60%, 70% of national income in public debt. So I'm not saying they should do this, but it's important to realize that-- many people would be shocked if we had to pay rent to the private owners of the schools to which we send our children. So I'm not saying they should do this. But it's important to realize that in a way, this is already what they are doing. Because when you have a public debt that's bigger then the value of your public assets, in effect what you have to pay in interest payment for your public debt can be higher than what would be the rental value of your public asset. So it's a bit more abstract because it goes through the financial intermediation system. But in the end, it's very concrete. Right now in Italy, they are paying 5%, 6% of GDP each year in interest payment, whereas the total budget of their entire public university system is about 1% of GDP. And so is this the right way to prepare the future for the new generation? It's not entirely clear. So I try to put these issues into historical perspective. Britain in the 19th century is a country where the holders of public debt, the rentiers of public debt, are very powerful, not only in the novels of Jane Austen but also in the real politics of the time. And they manage to get the country to repay during an entire century 2%, 3% of GP in interest payment and budget surplus each year, which is more than the total education budget of Britain at that time. And during an entire century, the country reduces the vast public debt of 200% of GDP that came from the Napoleonic War to 20%, 30% of GDP at the eve of World War I. So it worked, but it took an entire century of repaying interest payment. And I would not like Europe to make the same mistake today. But anyway, that's one of the things for which history can be useful. So let me also mention, very quickly, some of the particular features of capital and inequality in the United States of America. And let me say inequality in America has a different structure as in Europe. And this was already like this in the 19th century, where you have-- as we like to say, the Land of Opportunity. Capital accumulated in the past matters less than Europe, partly because of perpetual population growth, which is in a way a way to reduce the level of inherited wealth. And at the same time, this is a land of slavery, which is in a way the most extreme form of property relation. And I just finished yesterday reading Sven's book, and I regret that I couldn't read it before when I wrote my book. But certainly, the importance of slavery-- we all know after Sven's book the importance it had in the development of capitalism in this country and in global history as well. I try also in my book to illustrate this in the following manner-- if you look at the total value of wealth, say, in Britain in the 18th century, you have very high ratio of wealth to income. If you look in the US-- so this is with the same scale-- you can see that the ratio is much lower, in particular because the value of agricultural land is much lower. So land prices are very low in the US in the 19th century. We all know this. Tocqueville wrote about this, and Tocqueville thought one of the origins of the democratic spirit of America was that everybody could own land and everybody can access land. So if you just own land, you cannot be very rich, because there is so much land that the price of land is very small. And generally speaking, the total value of everything there is to own in the country is not very high. So you cannot be very rich just by owning land, or you need to own a lot of land. But of course, if you have the clever idea to own not only the land but also the people who work on the land, then you can manage to be a lot richer. So here, this is the value of slaves-- the market value of slaves at that time. And then you get to wealth to income ratios that are much closer to the European level in the 19th century, with of course big variation between the South of the US and the North of the US. So that's why the US is, at the same time in the North, the place where wealth accumulated in the past is not very important, in particular because the value of agricultural land is very cheap. Whereas in the South, the slaves basically more than compensate for the lower value of the land. And this corresponds to an inequality structure and a structure of domination based on property which in many ways is much more violent than what you have in old Europe. So you have this contrast between different parts of the US and the particular relationship of the US with capital and with inequality which I try to emphasize in my book. And again, this is a very extreme case where property rights are socially historically determined. And you cannot just take them as given forever. They vary over time. They are a social construction. To give just another example of this, taking an example that is much, much closer to us today, from Germany. It's interesting. If you remember when I showed you the graph with Britain, France, and Germany that you have lower market values of capital assets in Germany as compared to France and Britain. And one interesting question is why? So very often, people talk about lower real estate prices in Germany, which could be related also to different housing market regulations in Germany. But in fact, the biggest part comes from lower stock market capitalization of corporations in Germany. And one interpretation is what we sometimes call stockholder capitalism, which is that shareholders in Germany have to share power a little more than in other countries with worker representatives, sometimes regional government. So that at the end of the day, the market value is less than the book value of a corporation. Now, apparently this doesn't prevent German companies from producing good cars. So the fact that you have a lower market value of companies is not bad in itself. And this example clearly illustrates that market and social values of capital can be very different and that more generally, property relations are socially, legally, historically determined. There are different ways to distribute power. So capital ownership is about power. And there are different ways to regulate and to organize power. I guess-- so this is a graph illustrating the ratio of market value and book value of corporations. That's, again, taken from my book. You can find it online. But you can see that for Germany-- so according to the textbook model of perfect capital markets, this ratio should always be equal to 100%. If you have the market value, the book value should be the same. In practice in Germany, it's always much less than 100%-- like, 60%, so the market value is 60%-- whereas in the US and the UK, it's more than 100%, at least in certain periods, or much closer to 100%. So the market and book values of companies differ systematically across countries. And this can be interpreted as evidence for different regulation of ownership and corporate power in different countries. I'm going to move very, very fast to the third point about the future of wealth inequality. This is where the gap between R and G is playing a role. So you can see that in everything I have cited so far, R minus G doesn't play any role. You know, I have to confess to you today that this whole thing about R and G was sort of a marketing trick which apparently worked very well. Because many people thought they could summarize the book with one equation, which of course, I don't believe that you can summarize 300 years of historical evolution about income and wealth with one equation. There are many different institutions, policy, historical forces that play a role. There is one area where R minus G might be important, which is if you want to understand the long-run evolution of the concentration of property. And here, the gap between R and G might be important. During most of human history, the gap was large for a simple reason, which is that the growth rate in pre-industrial society was close to zero. And so the rate of return to land was typically 4% or 5%. It could vary with legal arrangements and feudalism, but it was certainly never 0%. Now, one of the findings of my book is that the modern industrial revolution did not change its basic relationship between R and G as much as one might have expected. It's only really the big shocks of the 20th century that have completely turned upside down this relation between at least net of tax, net of destruction, rate of return, and growth rate-- because of the shock due to the war, because of the very fast growth of the post-war period. Now, in the future, it looks as if growth rates, in particular for population, will be less than what they were in the past. And competition between countries to attract capital, maybe also financial deregulation, can contribute to high rate of return, in particular for high wealth portfolio. One of the problems is that there's probably too little transparency about global wealth dynamics, and particularly cross-border financial assets. And I think this is a problem in rich countries. But this is even more a problem in emerging countries, in particular China, Latin America, Africa, where a very big part of the capital stock is owned either by local or foreign elites through off-shore assets and tax events, which makes it very difficult for democratic regulation of inequality. And that's a big challenge for the future. So I'm not going to present this in a detailed manner, just to mention that if you look at data coming from wealth rankings-- so this is a table coming from the Forbes' billionaire's wealth rankings-- it looks as if the very top wealth groups at the world level are rising a lot faster than average wealth. Let me make clear that this is not particularly reliable data. It's hard sometimes to know how the Forbes people compute their ranking. But we live at a time-- it's a bit sad-- I would prefer to read the IMF publication or Eurostat publication or US government publication to know about wealth dynamics. But you wouldn't find the data, partly because for lack of transparency and automatic transmission of information about cross-border financial assets. So we have to do with what we have. So in my book, I am very pragmatic with data sources. There's no perfect data sources. And so I use a little bit this Forbes Magazine at some point. And what you can see is that here you have a major divergence between the average wealth at the top and the average wealth in the world, which is not so easy to explain. Because sometimes people say, well, OK, but this is because you have a lot of new billionaires who make wealth. And indeed, the people at the top are not the same in 2013 and 1987. According to Forbes, the people at the top in 1987 are Japanese billionaires, which everybody has forgotten their name now. Whereas in 2013, you have Carlos Slim, you have Bill Gates, et cetera. But the fact that you have some mobility-- the fact that you have all of these new people at the top-- this, in itself, does not explain why the average wealth in this top group should rise three or four times faster than average wealth in the world. Because the fact that you have mobility-- in principle, you have some people who go down, you have some people who go up. If you were in an equilibrium of the world distribution of wealth, these two effects should more or less compensate each other. And the average wealth in this top group should rise more or less at the same speed as average wealth in the world. It's OK to have very rich people, very poor people, very middle people, as long as the different groups, in the long run, sort of rise at the same speed. Well, maybe not exactly at the same speed, but at speeds that are roughly comparable. But you cannot have forever average wealth at the top rising three, four times faster than average wealth for the entire world economy. Because if this was to continue, the share of global wealth going to the top will rise to 100%, which everybody would argue is probably too much. And I'm not saying it's going to go-- [LAUGHTER] I'm not saying it will go to 100%. I'm sure it will stop before that. But where exactly will it stop? Nobody really knows. And this is an issue. So why is this happening? I think there's been a lot of privatization in recent decades that have produced, in certainly Russian oligarchs who did not become rich just through saving. They became rich by becoming the owner of a large chunk of public assets at very low prices. This also happen-- if you take your-- Carlos Slim did not invent the cell phone. So innovation is important. But in many cases, you can see that at the origins of some of these large fortunes, you also have privatization. You have inheritance. You don't have the same level of violence which Sven talks to us about in his book on the history of capitalism. But you-- it's far from being steady. It's a process where being at the right time at the right place in order to acquire a big part of public property at a very low price played a big role in this time period. Now, in the future-- well, there's not much left to privatize in many of these countries. So this is not going to last forever. So that's one possible regulation. Also, by increasing the public debt, you can have large negative public wealth. And this can allow you to go further, even when there's not much left to privatize. I think part of the reason for this is also that financial deregulation has probably increased the inequality in access to high financial returns. So that's good for places like Harvard. Let me concludes this with this. So this is the return to Harvard endowment. So the reason I'm showing you university endowment is not to conclude with Harvard, but rather because at least these people publish data. That's a good thing about US universities, is that at least we know what they do with their portfolio. We know the ways they get the returns they get, which we don't know for the Forbes people. So that's why I use these data. So you can see that you have about 850 US universities with capital endowments. They have done very well-- 8.2% net of inflation, net of administrative costs between 1980 and 2010. And the higher the university endowment, the higher the return. So for Harvard, you have 10.2%, which is quite good. So I'm not saying it will be as high in the next decade. There were particular circumstances. But still, this illustrates the mechanisms through which inequality can feed itself. According to the textbook economic model, what a perfect capital market should do is that everybody should get the highest return on the planet. So you go to your bank with $100,000. And your money gets invested in China the next morning. And you get the highest yield on the planet. But in the real world, capital market don't seem to work exactly this way. And sometimes, if you are able to access very sophisticated financial products-- so the portfolio of Harvard is made of private equity, commodity derivatives, and complex financial products which are very difficult to access to if you just go to your bank with $100,000-- the management fees paid by Harvard right now are 0.5% percent per year, which is very small. But if you have $40 billion on demand, and you pay 0.5%, you can still spend more than $100 million each year to pay your group of financial advisors. And so if this allows you to get 10% rather than 6%, then that's worth it. That's interesting just to conclude-- to compare this with the amount of giving that was made to the Harvard endowment over the same time period. And over the same time period, you have of the order-- it's a little bit like the management fees now. It's of the order of 0.5% to 1% of the endowment each year in giving, so as compared by former students. So as compared to the financial return, this is really negligible. Well, sometimes that's useful if you want to get your children admitted to Harvard. But in terms of-- if you want to explain the rise of the endowment, the R is very important. So R versus G is an issue that can be quite significant when you look at large university endowments, which can also be important, maybe, for the world distribution of wealth, to try to explain why top wealth groups are doing structurally better than the middle class. Let me stop there. Sorry for being a bit too long. And thanks, again, for welcoming me in your program. SVEN BECKERT: Great. Thank you so much, Thomas. [APPLAUSE] DAVID KENNEDY: Thank you very much. It's wonderful to be here. And I appreciate the opportunity. I'm honored by the opportunity to comment a bit on the talk. It's terrific to welcome you here to the Harvard Law School, in part because your book, and also your talk, invites a kind of dialogue with policy and legal people. So how did this come about and what can be done about it are the kinds of mechanical questions you invite us to consider. And there's kind of a puzzle about the book. It's an incredibly institutionalist book wrapped up in a formula. And the marketing trick that you mentioned, again, may be somehow an explanation there. But this is a book that identifies an enduring link between capitalism and inequality in the form of a historic normal in which returns to capital outpace economic growth. So this is the formula with which you ended. And there would be a fascinating conversation to have, I think, about how differently in legal and economic specialties a word like capitalism, or even capital, comes to suggest a system within which you can speak about historical regularities that function as, in one way or another, logic or laws, and the way in which big stories get constructed out of data and then need to be broken down in these institutionalist ways. But rather than that, I think what I would do is just speak very briefly about the legal and international dimensions of the story-- to pick up the invitation that we engage with the question, what does law have to do with it? And so how do legal people think about inequality? Well, it's very common, I think, for legal people to accept a story about society that comes from economics-- and here Professor Piketty's is a perfectly useful one-- and then try to construct a response out of the available policy tools. And to a certain extent, the kinds of tools one thinks of are tax and transfer tools. So we can-- the transfer could happen through schooling. The transfer could happen even through a minimum wage. But the basic idea is, capitalism is what it is. And then if the state can't respond in this way, we have to live with it, in some sense. I want to propose a second kind of legal frame that's opened up by many of the examples in Professor Piketty's book, in which we get more down in the weeds where the actors and the structures that Professor Piketty interprets as part of the story of capitalism get put together, and where they might seem to be, in one or another way, more plastic. I mean, it's obvious, but easy to forget-- and he stresses this repeatedly-- that the foundations of economic life are legal-- capital, labor, money. Law doesn't just regulate these things. It doesn't just tax them. It also creates them. And it could create them in different ways with different distributional outcomes and potentially different trajectories for society over time. So just as there are alternatives to capitalism, there are also alternatives within in. And a legal question would be, how do we figure that out? What are the alternatives? And how does law set us on one path rather than another? So on the micro side, you could imagine drilling down beneath aggregate institutional identities, like labor and capital and state and so forth, to think about people facing each other in some kind of struggle over gains in which their relative power vis-a-vis one another is a function of their entitlements and their vulnerability. So in this sense, Ricardo was right. Rent is everything. Economic gain arises from a legal entitlement, whether it's a land or anything else, to exclude somebody else from an element of value. And a map of entitlements at the micro level would be a map of coercive powers and the distribution of bargaining power, but also-- that makes it sound like we're going to have a discussion. The distribution of the coercive ability to force someone to forgo gain that they might otherwise have hoped to enjoy. There are lots of obvious examples-- intellectual property, inheritance law, and so forth. And you bring up a number of them, also, in your talk. On the macro side, there'd be the process by which legal powers and vulnerabilities bunch. And here, I think, you were just getting to that at the end with your story about the Harvard endowment. And how is it that, to those who have more and more accounts, what is the process by which the status of forces between groups, not between individuals, is settled in society-- between creditors and debtors, local workers and foreign investors, and so on? And how is it that the outcomes of past struggles bear down on current deals? So seeing it as a past settlement that arose through a bargain and a competition gives a different flavor to the idea of the weight of history than imagining it simply as an accumulation of money. And then there'd be a dynamic element. Virtuous and vicious cycles would get going as legal arrangements made it easier or more difficult for differences to compound. So if we went at inequality with these legal ideas in mind, I think we might come up with a wider range of responses than transnational taxes or stronger federal regional authority, and so forth. A long march through the institutions could re-jiggle things in ways that would strengthen the relative coercive powers of people that we wanted to favor and promote more virtuous cycles between the haves and the have-nots, without a large theory about how much inequality was good or bad for capitalism or the development of the society as a whole, simply as an effort to strengthen the hands of those whose coercive powers are now too few. And it's not that difficult to figure out how, because people have been struggling intensely over legal regimes in these terms for a long time. You mention rent control as a very important struggle over the value and use potential of some forms of real estate. But you could also alter contract and employer law to empower unions. You could change housing and local government law to link housing for the rich to public services for the poor. You could change the rules of finance and consumer protection to shift power from creditors to debtors and penalize exploitative financialization, and so on. Indeed, you can shift the power between identity groups-- men and women, blacks and whites, old and young, future generations and current generations-- in similar ways. So that's the legal background. There are lots of ways to address the dynamics of inequality beyond transfer payments from wealthier to poorer. It's possible somehow to link leading and lagging sectors or regions, either within a country or between countries, to one another productively. So a few words about the international dimensions of the story. The data that Professor Piketty brings together is comparative national data on inequality within one country, which he's extended to quite a number of countries and is now extending, as we've heard, to even more. But these comparisons, as he acknowledges, are extremely difficult. And it's hard to say what this means about inequality at the global level. So does tax data, for example, exaggerate the inequality between countries where countries have really different ways of understanding income reporting and different cultural practices with regard to taxation? But whatever the story is about national inequality, it seems to me global inequality is harder to assess or understand what we think about. So within a country, the existence of the 1% rankles when other people's incomes are stagnant at some point. But imagine the following-- imagine it turned out that global poverty and inequality could be reduced if we empowered a super-rich class of financiers-- the 0.01 percenters-- and we allowed wages to fall in the richest quarter of countries, through a combination of financialization on the one hand and factor price equalization for labor on the other hand. If we knew that that was true, Professor Piketty's findings about in-country inequality might look very different. You could still jiggle things to improve equality, but financialization might not require so much super-charging of the rich. But if you thought that it did and that overall global inequality might thereby be reduced, you might have a different attitude towards it. Moreover, the international situation is also a legal situation. The global, economic, and political space is intensely legalized. And you can map legal arrangements globally that enable the capture of rent and contribute to center-periphery dynamics, just as you can at the domestic level. So there's a global rent story-- who may coerce a greater share of the gains from, let's say, natural gas exploitation-- Qatar or Chevron? The answer will lie in legal arrangements-- sovereign powers, control over technology, know-how, monopoly power, the law regulating finance and corporate law-- all those will affect who gets the gain from the natural gas that's being pumped out in the Gulf. What powers permit upgrading or force downgrading in a global value chain? The law governing the ability to garner innovation rents, antitrust law, and so forth. And there's a global story about center-periphery relations. What legal arrangements speed the compounding of gains? The mobility of capital, the fragmentation of jurisdictions, the fact that private rights travel more easily than public powers-- all these things change the speed with which some wealth aggregates and others do not. Just as the terms of trade between Detroit and its suburbs-- that's where I'm from-- is a function of everything from jurisdictional boundaries to rules about school finance, so the transnational dualisms that we see between regions and countries are a function of international economic law and international private law. So it's a complicated story. And in short, geography matters and geography is a legal construct-- who can do what in relationship to whom with what force? So to sum up, I think Professor Piketty has identified a tendency. And to explore how the tendency arises, how it's sustained, and might be changed, requires that we somehow open up the hood and look inside market capitalism to see how it's put together. And it turns out the glue that distributes is law. Thank you. [APPLAUSE] SVEN BECKERT: Thank you so much, David. STEPHEN MARGLIN: I'm, like the other speakers here, honored to be part of this program. This is a magnificent book. [LAUGHTER] [APPLAUSE] We all knew that inequality was rising. What we lacked was any kind of historical and international perspective to put this in. And his book has done this in spades. It's really opened up a whole new field of research. And the economics profession should be in Professor Piketty's debt for some time to come. This book is a classic. [LAUGHTER] It's right up there with the other books that economists often talk about but rarely have read. I could tell you a story about that, too, but I'm only allowed 10 minutes. SVEN BECKERT: Yeah, five. STEPHEN MARGLIN: Five, he said. But he really meant 10. You know, there's been inflation-- a lot of inflation. SVEN BECKERT: Right, since yesterday. STEPHEN MARGLIN: This fellow Jordan Ellenberg did scientific research on Professor Piketty's book. And he discovered that few people had got beyond page 26, which made it the new record. The record up to that time, he said, was held by Stephen Hawking for a book most owned and least read. And now that record has passed to Professor Piketty. [LAUGHTER] I have to say-- and I hope you'll forgive me for this, too-- I and the other speakers didn't know this is a 500-plus page book. We didn't know what part of it Professor Piketty was going to emphasize, so we had to prepare our remarks on the basis of the book and not on the talk. I did not know that R greater than G was a marketing ploy. I, like many others, thought that that really was a theoretical argument-- sorry, theoretical cum empirical argument-- that structured the book. So I'm actually going to spend a lot of time-- I can't spend a lot of time. I'm going to spend a large fraction of time on that particular point. But I should say before that that much of what's of value in this book is quite independent of that inequality-- and a good thing, too, because I will suggest that that inequality should not surprise anybody. It is not a contradiction of capitalism. It's exactly what you would expect. It's the norm. Moreover, it is not, in itself, destabilizing. I'm writing it here with a subscript, which you don't usually see-- the subscript y to emphasize that this is about the growth of income and output, not the growth of a capital stock, though those two are, obviously, related. Here are three brief excerpts from the book about the importance of this inequality. The first one, I think really is very important, and I think it's absolutely correct. If you think about it, it's not a contradiction of capitalism. It's a contradiction of capitalism with democracy. We had a chat at lunch about how these two are related-- inconclusive as you might expect such a chat conversation to be. But this really is, I believe, a contradiction, but not a contradiction of capital, not a contradiction of capitalism, not a contradiction of growth. The last statement is just flat-out wrong-- just flat-out wrong. Piketty's laws are correct. He has three of them. We only will emphasize one, but there are three laws. And they're absolutely and invariably correct, because they are laws of arithmetic. They're not laws of economics. They're not laws, certainly, of capital. Here they are displayed. We don't have any time to go through them in detail. But the notation-- I'm sorry, I realize that this is inside baseball, because if you didn't get beyond page 26, then this is not going to be crystal clear. But if you did get beyond page 26, it should be familiar. But I'm going to pick them up. So the first one of his laws is that the capital share is equal to the rate of return on capital times the capital output ratio. Well, that's true, because they're both the same thing. So that's fine. The second law-- and there's two versions of it-- one is in terms of the rate of growth of the capital stock, which is why I made the distinction in the first place. The other is in the rate of growth of income. But they both-- whichever way you put it, they are both arithmetic laws. From those, you can deduce a third law which is not exactly Piketty's law, but it gives the condition under which-- how much time do I have? That's OK, we'll get there. It gives the condition under which R will exceed the rate of growth of output. And that condition is subject to a difference between the incremental capital output ratio and the average capital output ratio, a relationship between the rate of saving in the economy and the capital share. So basically, as long as the capital share exceeds the rate of savings, then R will be greater than G. It's as simple as that. Normally, that's the case under capitalism. It's not logically necessary, but it is normally the case. Nor is it a reason why the capital concentration must grow. Because Piketty's argument is that, as in the 19th century, the likely course-- the course for the last 30, 40 years and the likely course in the future-- is that the share of profits, the share of capital, will grow. And it will grow as against a constant rate of saving. And therefore, as that ratio grows, as alpha becomes larger and larger than the savings rate, R will grow relative to G. As alpha grows, as the capital share grows, inequality will grow, because capital income is more concentrated than labor income. That's the story. I have to say that this is not an empirical argument. It's a theoretical argument. And the theory, I have to say, in this book, does not match the empirical originality, perseverance, intelligence that the book shows. The theory is, at best, elementary. And it just doesn't come to the level that the empirical arguments come to. First question-- why does beta rise over time? Why does the capital output ratio-- I'm sorry, rise or fall over time? Well, this is what Piketty and his colleagues said in a companion paper to this volume. They say it's-- in short, capital is back, capital output ratio is growing, because low growth is back. Well, that's true as an accounting identity. The two have to move together. We see that from the fact that those equations are necessarily logically true. But it doesn't say anything about what's causing what. It doesn't say anything about what's causing what. Two more minutes. So here is the same thing-- that if you look at the rate of growth of the capital stock that, as I said, the rate of return on capital will exceed the rate of growth, provided the share of capital exceeds-- income exceeds the savings rate. Here is a diagram that indicates a relationship between rate of return on capital, rate of growth of the capital stock, and a very simple assumption about the economy-- that there are two classes of people. There are rentiers, patrimonial capital which is passed down from generation to generation. And then there's a middle class of wage earners and savers. Leave the poor out of this. They don't save. They don't enter into accumulation. And the solid line gives the relationship between-- I'm almost done-- between the growth of the capital stock and the rate of return on capital. So yeah, in most of this, you're in a region where R exceeds the rate of growth. And you're not necessarily there. Here's a region where, at low rates of return, the rate of growth will exceed the rate of return. So it's not logically necessary. But the main point is that each of these corresponds to a stable division of capital. It does not necessarily imply any kind of increasing concentration. So look at this purple colored part. This is all a situation in which Piketty's inequality holds. But wealth accumulated in the past is not growing more rapidly than output and wages. They're growing at exactly the same rate. So there's no necessary tendency for income inequality to worsen. Is this a theory? No, it's not a theory. It's an argument that says that a theory is missing from Piketty's Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Does that make the book any less magnificent? No, not in the slightest. Because what Piketty has done is give us the basis for thinking about, theorizing about, how the situation of the present is similar to the situation in the past, how the situation of the present is likely to evolve in the future. And for this, we're all in your debt. SVEN BECKERT: Thank you so much, Steve. [APPLAUSE] CHRISTINE DESAN: So I've been asked-- can you hear me? I've been asked to stay here to be quicker. And that's OK, because I feel like a justice. It's the only time in my life I'll ever feel like that, on the court's podium. Thomas Piketty has changed the debate over inequality. His arguments are arresting. They transform impressions into trends. And then they confront us with the trends. His data is compelling. Even those who qualify one aspect or another accept the larger picture as persuasive. His work is transparent. He makes his data and his arguments very clear and available to all of us. And we are a large audience. There are overflow rooms in this case. I could continue with the praise, but I'm supposed to be quick. So I'm going to get to one theme. And I have a few questions wrapped into this discussion of one of Professor Piketty's themes. So he concludes, his last chapter concludes, this way-- if democracy is someday to regain control of capitalism, it must start by recognizing that the concrete institutions in which democracy and capitalism are embodied need to be reinvented again and again. So his focus is the concrete institutions that embody democracy and capitalism. That's an invitation to the many of us whose lives and work revolves around institutions. And that's political scientists. It's sociologists. It's historians. But it's also members of the public. And it's also law students and lawyers. I'm going to talk very particularly to the latter-- law students, legal historians, lawyers-- because our work is in institutional design. Law puts political determinations into effect by institutionalizing them through legislation, through regulations, through court decisions, through norms, through the creation of categories. Law implements political conclusions. It builds the institutions we inhabit. So I want to be concrete about that. I'll just give two examples-- one very stark and one more sweeping as an institutional matter. The stark one picks up very much on what David Kennedy said. So Professor Piketty gives us many aggregates-- capital stock, economic growth-- these things only have meaning because of their legal components, components like wages and assets. So David's beautiful description of legal assets as depending on the settlement of previous bargaining processes-- I was going to come up with an-- I have an example of an asset. But in fact, Professor Piketty's presentation made me cross that out. Slavery-- slaves are the most obvious example of an asset the value of which, insofar as people had a market value, it was because slavery was legal. So an asset depends on its legal definition. So that's the stark example. I want to move to the more sweeping institutional example. And this is to show the impact of legal design on capitalism, or to look at capitalism as an institutional form. So I'm going to preface it with a question to Professor Piketty. What do you mean by capitalism? Do the concrete institutions that make up capitalism hang together somehow? Can we understand capitalism as something? Why does capitalism matter if returns to capital are higher than economic growth in earlier ages, as well as our own? I think there are answers to this question. I think they matter. I think we need to have a coherent definition of capitalism if we're going to take it on, if we're going to rethink it. So here's an answer. I'm going to give a very specific answer about legal architecture or institutional architecture of capitalism. In 1700, capitalism was redesigned. We get a whole series of new institutions. We get new forms of money and finance. They depend on each other. They re-engineer wealth and production. They create a new architecture for the market. And that architecture, that infrastructure, is what we call capitalism. So I'm going to identify just four elements to the new architecture. First, we get the invention of circulating, credible public debt, which as Professor Piketty points out is extremely important. Public bonds look boring, but they are the first financial instrument pitched to the general public. A public bond is an instrument that asks people, regular individuals, to lend to the public, lend to the government, and it gives them a reward for doing so. That's an innovation, one that has legal import. So it changes the way people think about material interest. It changes the way they think about self-interest. It makes it acceptable, even patriotic to follow one's self-interest. And governments soon grant public creditors a right to repayment. This is the financial instrument that Jane Austen's gentlemen are holding-- for good reason. This is in Professor Piketty's lovely description. Second, we get the innovation of modern cash. The innovation of modern cash follows the innovation of public bonds. Public bonds furnish the collateral, the security, against which national banknotes are issued. So banknotes are issued against public bonds by national banks, and they travel widely against public bonds. Cash backed by public bonds breaks England and later European societies out of the monetary scarcities of the Middle Ages. And those scarcities were scathing. Modern money-- modern banknotes-- by contrast issues much more readily than silver coin. It issues when national bank investors take bonds and issue bank notes to the governments that are borrowing from them. And here, just as in the case of public debt, there's a conceptual innovation-- a change. The new design puts a premium on profit-oriented calculation. That calculation becomes the pump for money creation legally-- legal change. Third, after public debt and national bank cash come capital markets. So public debt and national bank cash together create capital markets and provide the money to fuel them. After all, public debt is a legally transferable security. People get together. They start to exchange it. We know the coffee houses in Exchange Alley in London where they start to do this. They represent a critical mass of traders trading a stable security. And given that starting point, private securities begin to get traded in the same places after public securities. Increasingly, the money used to invest in capital markets will be modern cash, modern bank money-- the more copious cash of the modern world, not the old, awkward commodity money of the Middle Ages. So notice the synergy between public debt, public bonds, national bank notes, and capital markets that we're building. Again, there's a conceptual component. Capital markets direct investment in ways that can be tracked. They transform speculation, long despised, into something else-- or so thought Justice Holmes. So here's Holmes. When he sees the cumulative effect of speculation conducted on an exchange, he calls it a market. So he says in a landmark case about futures trading that futures trading was not gambling, because speculation, as he puts it, by competent men is the self-adjustment of society to the probable. Its value is well known. The speculation via Justice Holmes is ordained beneficial, informative, revelatory in law, which would otherwise terminate it as gambling. A last development-- after public debt, national bank money, and capital markets-- all new, legally engineered institutions, we get commercial banks-- a huge expansion of commercial banks. They can lend in a unit. Everyone recognizes that's national bank money. They can borrow from each other. They lend into the capital markets, often holding public bonds as security. They effectively lend more than they hold because they can be rescued by the national banks, now known as central banks, when they fail-- which is regularly, given their highly leveraged structure. So the asset bubbles that Professor Piketty is talking about come from the structure of commercial banks. As a result, because of the expansion of commercial banks, the money supply expands more than 65-fold in the 19th century. The industry of banking gains the profits on money creation denominated in the national currency, in those national bank notes. Taxpayers go into debt to rescue and revive the system when it fails. The cost of rescuing banks, according to Reinhart and Rogoff almost doubles public debt on average in the three years following a banking crisis. So here, too, is a conceptual dimension-- a shift. Money appears to be something privately created once it comes from these commercial banks. And 97% of the money supply in the modern world comes from commercial banks, not the government. My point-- this architecture is modern capitalism. These institutions-- public debt, modern cash, capital markets, commercial banks, I could add money markets if we had more time-- they produce the market. In this market, it is possible to accumulate wealth to a prodigious extent. So the wealth that follows from capital investment and that takes financial form-- this is the modern structure of capital that Professor Piketty showed. From agricultural we move to business capital to financial capital. This was his slide 4.6, I noticed. This is the new composition of capital. These are the forms of wealth that he flags for us. And that wealth is wrapped up in legal forms. It's enabled. It is, basically, a function of these forms. Ironically, many people miss the public architecture of capitalism altogether. They see powerful markets. They see cash. They see capital. They see securities. They see banks. They fail to see that these are institutions that we have built with a public infrastructure, with public funds, and with law. So why does that oversight matter-- that is, the failure to see the architecture? If you overlook its public engineering, then the architecture, the engineering appears to be a natural development, the market appears to be a product of autonomous forces, and the wealth produced on that market appears to be merited, or at least inevitable given the power of those forces. That impression is reinforced by the conceptual components, the conceptual momentum emphasized by the new institutions. So acts in one's own self-interest, profit-driven calculation, the tendency to see decentralized market decisions as the revelation of probability as opposed to speculation-- these dynamics gain stature as if they were more basic to human activity than public coordination and community. By contrast, we can make visible the institutional, the legal components of the architecture we've created. We can revise it. We can find new ways to structure capital. We could impose a more progressive tax. I totally agree with Professor Piketty. There are many other revisions we can make. That's a third-- a last question to him. I think he agrees, because focusing on a wealth tax alone leaves the rest of the architecture uncontested when it's possible that that architecture-- it seems to me that architecture-- is at the center of the problem. So to return to Professor Piketty's injunction to us, if democracy is someday to regain control of capitalism, it must start by recognizing that the concrete institutions in which democracy and capitalism are embodied need to be reinvented again and again. I couldn't agree more. [APPLAUSE] SVEN BECKERT: Thank you so much, Christine. We now have-- we will be able to go a little bit over time. So we can probably go until 10 past 4:00. And I hope you're going to be able to stay here. And we want to do so to also give you a chance to participate in this discussion. So I ask Professor Piketty not to respond right away to these comments, but I want you to have an opportunity to ask questions or make comments. And there are two microphones at the center of the room. So if you want to ask something, please go there. And keep your question very short. And whatever you say, it should have a question mark at the end, OK? And we have already two big topics on the table, which we probably cannot resolve here. The one is the theory, and the other one is the legal political construction of markets. AUDIENCE: Hello, my name is Sabata Lapontes. I'm a college student from Brazil. It's a great honor to be here. And my question is, when you talk about a country like Brazil, who is in the middle income trap, which means that we do have very low wages, but we also don't have high technology. You still would prescribe the recommendations you have in the book? Thank you. AUDIENCE: Hello, my name is Patrick. Thank you so much for being here, Professor Piketty. So I'm going to ask a more unconventional question. If you could have dinner with anyone in history, who would it be? SVEN BECKERT: One more. AUDIENCE: My name's Julian Duran. I'm a first-year student at the college. And my question is, a lot of your critics say that your proposed capital tax would end up taxing innovation, which would, of course, harm economic growth. So I'm just wondering how you would respond to criticisms such as those. SVEN BECKERT: OK, so why don't we take these questions now, and then we'll move on. So please wait for a moment. Thomas. THOMAS PIKETTY: Oh, OK. Well, let me say a few words, also, to David and Steve and Christine. Thanks a lot for your comments, which make me think a lot. One or two quick remarks-- I really liked, David, what you said about geography as a legal construct and the international dimension of this discussion about the legal system. This made me see-- I wrote recently a paper that's not included in my book about trying to measure inequality at the level of the Middle East as a whole-- so forgetting about the national boundaries, and taking together this 250, 300 million inhabitants from Egypt to Iran. And so if you do that, basically what-- you find something which is very of use, but which is important, which is that you have a level of inequality of incomes that is much higher than any other region in the world, and in particular, much higher than in Latin America or that country like Brazil, which are usually viewed as the most unequal countries. But given the international inequality between-- at some point in my book, I mention Egypt. The total education budget for all schools in Egypt, which is a country with almost 100 million people, is 100 times less than all resources going to countries with no population a few hundred kilometers away in the Gulf. So the level of international inequality that you have here is such that if you put all these countries together, even though within country inequality is not necessarily very high, the total inequality is much higher. So I think playing around with these boundaries and trying to look at inequality beyond the existing boundaries-- which, of course, are legal constructs. So in the case of the Middle East, some of them are being redrawn right now. So these are legal constructs, and these are changing legal constructs. And also, some of them have been constructed by the West, of course, and have been supported by the West. I was very influenced as a student by two major political events. One was the fall of the Berlin Wall, of course. I was 18 in 1989. But the other one in 1990, 1991, was the first Gulf War where, in effect, we were protecting a given set of frontiers. And these are legal constructs. And this goes together with the level of inequality that is clearly part of the story of what's going on. So probably in the book, I take too much the nation state as given, and I don't go enough beyond the existing boundaries to study inequality. But this is something that should be done more. Let me say a few words to Steve about the marketing trick and R bigger than G. So what I mean by marketing trick is that there is a lot more-- many other mechanisms, institutions, policies that play a big role in the book independently of R bigger than G. Now, let me also mention that in itself, you can have R bigger than G in a world with perfect equality-- no inequality at all. All what this means is if the growth rate is 1% and the rate of return on average is 5%, all this means is that you could be in a society with perfectly equal property of capital. And all this implies is that the owner of-- each family needs to reinvest 20% of its capital income and can consume the other 80% so as to ensure that its wealth rises at the same speed as the size of the economy. So you could have a perfect egalitarian model-- a representative agent model, as economists say-- where R is bigger than G. You have perfect equality, and everything is perfectly fine. So in a way, yes, this is a normal situation, because if R was smaller than G, then it means that you would need to reinvest even more than the return to your capital in order to ensure that your capital grows as fast as the size of the economy, which would be really stupid. What's the point of being an owner if you need to reinvest more than the return to your ownership? So this is really the very least you can ask from capital ownership, which is that R is bigger than G. Otherwise, what's the point? So in itself, R bigger than G is not-- there's no problem with it. It could come with a perfectly egalitarian society. [INAUDIBLE] Now, the problem is that in practice, there are many forces that make wealth unequal. You have many shocks in the life of families and in the process of wealth accumulation and wealth transmission. So different families have different numbers of children. They die at different ages. Some make very good investments. Some go bankrupt. Some have very high wages. Some have low wages. The point is that for a given variance of all these other shocks, a bigger gap between R and G will tend to amplify this variance, and will tend to get the economy to converge to a level of wealth concentrations that will be a steeply rising function of of R bigger than G. So this is the basic theoretical model that I have in mind. This is exposed in the technical appendix to Chapter 10. That's available online. You can go look. That's exposed in the Science paper as well. This is a well-known theoretical model, but here I try to take it seriously, which is that a small difference in R bigger than G can indeed magnify other shocks. But you need other shocks. If you don't have all these other shocks to rate of return, to labor income, to demographics-- in itself, R bigger than G does not produce inequality. But if you have all these other shocks, then it will tend to magnify inequality. And I think that's part of the explanation for why wealth concentration is so high in pretty much every society up until World War I, is because of that. In particular, why is wealth concentrated almost as much or ever more in France in 1914 than in France in 1789? Which the elite at the time in France did not want to believe this. They thought, we have modern property, modern growth, equality and property regimes. We are not in the Ancien Regime anymore, so we should have equality. Well, except that in fact, the concentration of wealth was just as large as a century and a half before. And I think part of it is because the gap between R and G did not decline because of modern capitalism and because of the Industrial Revolution. Which brings me to the very important question raised by Christine-- what's my definition of capitalism? Well, I like your definition. It's a set of institutions you describe as very important. Probably Sven would add that the development of new appropriation of land in the colonies, in the New World, the invention-- or at least the development-- of slavery at a scale that was unknown before played a big role. So I think all these different institutions and legal institution and coercive powers-- to take the terms of David-- are critical to the development of capitalism. But one of the messages of my book is that in the end, modern capitalist institution and modern Industrial Revolution did not affect this basic inequality between the rate of return and the growth rate as much as one might have expected in the long run. So of course, the growth rate increased from 0% in preindustrial society to 1% or 2% in the long run in modern industrial societies. But the rate of return also increased. And so the gap between the two did not change that much. Of course, it depends on legal regimes. The legal rules can affect this gap a lot. So this is not-- I don't take it as an act of God. It is a rule of law, and this can be changed by different legal regimes. But by and large, this big gap was there before industrial capitalism, and it will probably be there after industrial capitalism. So you have metamorphoses of property structure, but this structural relation is still there. Let me move to the questions that were raised after that. Brazil is-- do you have the same policy recommendations for Brazil than for the US or France? I think no. Each country has its own set of institutions and policy to develop. Each country has its own particular intimate history of inequality. So Brazil, of course, is a country with a lot of inequality, which a lot of it comes from its particular history. This was the last country where slavery was abolished. There was one-third of the population that was slave in 1880 years as compared to 10% in the US. So slavery took a dimension. So there are historical routes to inequality that are different in different countries. Now, still some of the solution that I mention in the book I think can be of interest even if each country has to find its own way. In terms of progressive taxation, Brazil is a country where you have very large indirect tax, consumption tax. So you pay your electricity bill, you pay a 30% tax. But then the inheritance tax right now in Brazil is 3%. So if you inherit millions, tens of millions, you pay 3% tax. And I think probably you could reduce the first one and increase the second one. So there are issues about taxation in order to finance better public services and public education in Brazil, where I think there are things to learn from other countries. But that doesn't mean that there's a one-size-fits-all policy. I will skip the dinner questions, because it's-- I don't quite know what to answer to this. Jesus Christ would have been-- [LAUGHTER] Anyway, so the last questions-- I'm sorry that I didn't keep track. Yes, progressive taxation and innovation. The historical evidence is that it really depends how you structure your level of progressivity. If you had very high tax rate on everybody, including people who are just starting new accumulation of wealth, then that's probably not good for innovation. But if you have very high progressivity only at the very top end, the evidence-- in particular from this country, in the US-- the US is a country where between 1930 and 1980, on average the top income tax rate was 82%, which is really as high as it can possibly be. Well, there was state income tax in addition to that. But this applied to very high income levels, typically above $1 million in annual incomes. And if anything, the productivity growth of the US economy-- well, apparently this didn't kill American capitalism, otherwise we would have noticed it in a 50-year period. And if anything, productivity growth was higher in the '50s, '60s, '70s than what it has been since the Reagan years. Probably because paying top managers, as I say during my talk, $10 million per year rather than $1 million is not so useful. And so I think the evidence is that, of course, if you have 80% tax rate on anybody who's making $100,000 or $200,000, probably you will have a different effect. So it really depends how you structure your progressive tax system. SVEN BECKERT: OK, let's take two more questions, very short, and then we'll unfortunately, have to come to an end. AUDIENCE: Hello, Professor Piketty. My question is also pretty connected to that case of endogenous growth that was the previous question about. Have you tried to estimate in some way what part of the change in the net worth of the richest individuals came either from buying new assets, change of prices of assets they already have, or from creating entirely new kinds of assets? Like, for example, building a cell phone network in Mexico. SVEN BECKERT: Thank you. AUDIENCE: If capital tax were to be imposed, if somebody owns assets which do not produce cash flow, does that mean that that person would have to sell assets in order to pay their taxes? And would this lead to a market crash in that case? Thank you. THOMAS PIKETTY: Hm. Well, just to start with the last question. The property tax-- there is already a wealth tax in the US and in most countries. This is called the property tax. It's just that it's based on your real estate property. But this is already half of household wealth, so this is half of a wealth tax, if you will. And I think the main reason why it's half of a wealth tax is because this was created a long time ago-- 200 years ago in the US, or actually in Britain or in France, [? taxe financiere ?], which is the equivalent of the property tax, that was created by the Revolution-- at a time where wealth was mostly either land or real estate. And there was limited financial wealth and financial liability. So that's why this tax was created, as a tax of real property. But the way it works is that indeed, if you have a lot of property but you don't get any income out of it-- so if you have a secondary residence everywhere in the country, but you don't rent them, you don't do anything with them, and you just spend one night per month in each of them-- then your property tax will be more than your income, in the extreme case where you have zero income and you have property there. And so yes, you will have to sell some of your property to pay your property tax. But I don't think anybody's asking that such people should be exempt from property tax. I've never heard anybody asking for this. So I think the whole point of a property tax or wealth tax is that, indeed, if you have a lot of wealth but very little income, and you're just sitting on your properties, then, well, you will have to sell some of it so that other people who know what to do with the wealth will do something with it. And that's the whole logic of property taxation. It's always been like this. So that's why this issue of how much you should tax the stock of property versus the flow of new income is complicated. In France, a big proponent of wealth taxation was Maurice Allais, who was a Nobel Prize winner in economics. And I can tell you, he was not left wing at all. He was a very right-wing person. But he thought that we should tax the stock of property and not at all the income flow, so as to put incentives on people to get a high return on their property. Now, it's too extreme, because sometimes the rate of return you get is just partly due to bad luck. So if you are a company, you're making losses-- maybe if you keep paying a tax on the stock of wealth, you will pay as much tax as a company making huge profits which maybe will put you in bankruptcy, so that's probably not a good idea. So you want to find a balance between how much you tax the stock and how much you tax the flow. And each tax system has components of the two. The problem is that sometimes these tax systems were set up 200 years ago and did not adapt to the structure of wealth today. But I think we-- both kinds of taxation are useful. We have to find the right balance. SVEN BECKERT: OK, and on this note, unfortunately, we have to come to an end, not least because Professor Piketty is going to have to give another talk in 45 minutes elsewhere in Boston. But we could go on, obviously, for much longer. And in some ways, we should go on for much longer. This should be an invitation to continue to this debate on these issues. And we should thank Professor Piketty, not just for being here-- which, of course, we thank you for very much-- but also for instigating this really important debate. And thank you for joining us. [APPLAUSE]
Info
Channel: Harvard Law School
Views: 30,051
Rating: 4.8603172 out of 5
Keywords: Harvard Law School, HLS, Thomas Piketty, Christine Desan, David Kennedy, Sven Beckert, Stephen Marglin, Institute for Global Law and Policy
Id: 3ofjozfEr-U
Channel Id: undefined
Length: 122min 59sec (7379 seconds)
Published: Tue Mar 10 2015
Related Videos
Note
Please note that this website is currently a work in progress! Lots of interesting data and statistics to come.