GERALD NEUMAN: Welcome. I'm Gerald Neuman. I'm one of the directors of
the Human Rights Program, and we're very
pleased that you're all here for what
we think will be a very exciting conference
over the next day and a half, or half and a day, on the
subject of human rights in a time of populism. We actually started thinking
about this conference quite a while ago, after first
Brexit, then the US election, then watching a series
of elections in Europe-- some of which might be thought
to have turned out better than others. And the rise of populism as a
very common issue in the world scene, which has implications
for human rights, both in terms of
what are the policies that populist
governments in power adopt with regard to
their own populations. And also, the issue of the
rise of populism in countries and regions that have
been very supportive of the international
human rights system. I'm thinking particularly in
terms of the United States and the European
Union as supporters of the international human
rights system, in which there were now administrations
coming into power that may have very
different attitudes towards the international
human rights system. And what does that
mean for the system? So we wanted to
think more deeply about the questions of
populism and its relationship to human rights. What the causes of the
rise of populism may be, what the effects may
be, both domestically and in foreign policy. Look around the world
at some examples in different parts of the world
of the phenomenon of populism. Not thinking that we
would find uniform answers to all questions
in all the different parts of the world. And then, what lessons
the human rights system might learn from the
rise of populism. And what steps the human rights
system should take in order to deal with some new
challenges that may be arising as a result of populism. So that is the
program that we're going to be following for
the next day and a half. I'd like to thank
our co-sponsors. The Carr Center for Human Rights
Policy at the Kennedy School, the Institute for Global Law and
Policy here at the law school, the HLS Advocates for
Human Rights, the Harvard International Law Journal,
and the Harvard Human Rights Journal. And we'd also like to express
our appreciation for support that we've received
from the Asia Center at Harvard University
for this conference. So with that in
mind, we're going to move to the first panel. And you have programs. And fuller biographies of the
speakers are in the programs. We'll try to keep
introductions to a minimum. But briefly, if I can introduce
the panelists on this panel. First, immediately
to my right is Peter Hall, who is
the Krupp Foundation Professor of European
Studies and the Department of Government here at
Harvard and the author of numerous books and
articles on European politics and comparative
political economy. Next, Ruth Okediji, who
is the Jeremiah Smith Jr. Professor of Law here
at Harvard Law School, and a renowned scholar on
international intellectual property law and the role
of intellectual property in social and
economic development. And third, Matthew
Stephenson, who is Professor of Law here at HLS,
an expert on the application of positive political
theory to legal institutions and an international consultant
and advisor on anti-corruption. And with that, let me
give the floor to Peter. Thank you. PETER HALL: OK, thank you. Let me just see if this,
do I, do I point this at, what do I point this at? This? I don't point it at
anything, I just click it. All right. Well, let me begin by thanking
Gerry for including me in this very interesting event. I'm not a lawyer,
as you just heard. I'm a scholar of
European politics. And I'm going to
speak about the rising sources of support for populist
parties in the developed democracies. I think some of
what I have to say may travel to the developing
world, some of it may not. And I hope these very general
remarks that I'm going to make are, provide some useful
background for the discussions we're going to have more
specifically about human rights and some of the consequences
of support for populism. Can you hear me? Is this coming through the? It's fine. OK, so of course, to talk about
the sources of rising support for populism in 15
minutes is a little bit like trying to recite the
collected works of William Shakespeare in 15 minutes. So I can only make a few points. And each point I make
deserves more elaboration than I can give
it, but my hope is to be a little bit provocative. And I'm going to
treat three topics. Now the suspense ends and
we see if the slides work. So they do. So first of all, what is
contemporary populism? Gerry asked me in particular to
make some remarks about that. Why do more and more people
vote for populist candidates and parties? And thirdly, not quite the
same question, why now? What are the macro
level developments that inspire rising levels
of support for such parties, particularly in the
developed democracies? Populism has, of course,
been around for a long time, including in this
country in various forms and certainly in Latin America. At one time or
other, populism was seen as a Latin American sport. But it's now a
transnational phenomenon that I think is of
great importance. So how should we
define populism? It's a highly contestable topic. I'm not, I'm sure that
not everyone in this room will agree with my views. But let me just
simply state them. Populism has normative
connotations, as we all know. Positive for some,
negative for others. And yet each group on
either side of that issue wants to define populism
somewhat differently. And maybe they should
be welcome to do that, as Humpty Dumpty
would have advised. But the approach that I
would take to this is to ask, what is the real world
phenomenon of such importance that we need a label for it? And in my view, for at least
the European democracies and this country, this would be
radical right wing candidates who are mounting
new kinds of appeals in the contemporary era. And some commentators
in the blogosphere, and of course,
there's a huge set of blogosphere work on this,
some of those commentators suggest we should call these
right wing populists fascists, in order to preserve a
positive connotation, a more positive connotation
for the word of populism. But fascism entails
dictatorship, and that's not the case for most
of the parties and candidates that I look at. So I would define populist
parties or candidates as ones with a distinctive
set of appeals. Namely those who claim to
speak for a broad people. Not all people,
but a broad people. A people whose voice
is said to have been ignored by the political elite. A political elite
that's presented as corrupt or incompetent. And of course, that
definition owes a great deal to Jan-Werner Muller's
study of populism, to Cas Mudde, who's looked
at it carefully in Europe. And in those terms, populism
comes in both left wing and right wing variants. However, in the
developed democracies, there's more diversity
on the left, where it's much harder to assign
that what we might call radical left parties to the
populist category or non populist category. And of course, the
right wing variant is further distinguished by
a virulent nationalism, which typically presents
a globalization in its many dimensions
as a force to be opposed, and which demonizes
a set of out groups, including most
notably, immigrants of other races and religions. So note that on this
definition, politicians such as Jeremy Corbyn in
the UK or Bernie Sanders in this country, represent
an important phenomenon in their own right, an
important political phenomenon in my view certainly. Namely, radical critics of the
inequalities of capitalism, but they're not populists
per se, at least according to this definition. Now on this definition,
over the past two decades, support for populist candidates
has risen significantly in the developed, as well
as the developing world. And indeed, I think
this is one of the most important political
phenomena of our time. So where are those
votes coming from? Let me begin with two caveats. First, I'm going to emphasize
the transnational commonalities in what I think is a
global populist movement. I think there is a
transnational populist movement. This is probably the only issue,
only one of two issues maybe with which I agree
with Steve Bannon. But national variations
inevitably feed into this. As Tolstoy might have said,
all nations are unhappy, but every nation is
unhappy in its own way. Recent flows of immigration
in countries such as Germany matter more than they
do in some others. Corruption is more of an
issue in east central Europe than it is elsewhere. Votes for Brexit had something
to do with English nationalism. So there are elements of
national distinctiveness, which stand in the way of
monolithic generalization. But the second caveat is this. Where populist causes or
candidates win elections, as they did in the case
of the Brexit referendum, as some would argue they did in
the last presidential election here, where they
do, they inevitably do so on the back of a broad and
multiply motivated coalition. So as we know, more
than 90% of Republicans voted for Donald Trump. And many for reasons
that do not explain, for instance, why
the French might have voted for Marine Le Pen. So I think those are
two important caveats. And for this reason, I think
one of the most interesting dimensions of support for
populism in the developed democracies, is
why it has been so strong among white
working class voters. Not least because
that particular appeal spells political disaster for
the traditional center left. And in my view, the
ethnographic literature provides crucial clues about
why this might be the case. To take only one
well-known example, think of Arlie
Hochschild's interviews with folks in Louisiana. I think those interviews
reveal something important. They suggest that
many of these people feel left behind, in
this now familiar phrase. That is to say,
socially marginalized. And marginalized in both
economic and in cultural terms. So movement from a manufacturing
to a service economy, and some would say now
to a knowledge economy, have left many
people, as we well know, without the kind
of secure middle class living that they might
have once anticipated. And cultural
frameworks that have seen the elite embrace post
materialist values, and I'm thinking of many
people in this room, have left other people with
more traditional values feeling like strangers in
their own land, as Hochschild
argues in her book. So with Noam Gidron I've
been doing some research to see if this notion that
support turns on feelings of left behind,
see if that travels beyond the ethnographic
studies in which we see reports of that. And to do this, we
assess whether people feel socially marginalized
with a question that asks them about the
subjective social status. Namely, where they
think they sit on an overall social ladder. There's that question
on the slide. And we find in this
work, two things. First, white men without
a college education feel more marginal
to society today than they did 30
to 35 years ago. In 11 of the 12
countries for which we can find evidence for
this on this measure. So there is some evidence. It's a modest
decline, but there's some evidence of a
decline in this sense of subjective social status. An indication that
over time, there are groups of people,
particularly white men with less than
college education, who feel less central to society. I might note, by
the way, that when we look at women without
a college education, their subjective social status
has increased dramatically in these countries over time. They feel more
central to society on this measure at least, than
they did in the late 1980s. So that's the first
thing we find. Second, even when we
condition our estimations on a whole bunch
of other factors that might affect
how a person votes, based on data from 26
European countries in 2012, we find that this sense
of social marginalization, this sense that I'm no longer
at the center of my society, inclines people to
vote either for parties of the populous right or parties
of the populous left or radical left. Not necessarily populist. So a lot more could
be said about this, and I'm happy to say
more if there's time. But let me turn to the third
question I want to address, which is why now? What kind of developments
at the macro level have been leading people
toward these populist parties? And of course, we could spend
days arguing about this. And there's many
kinds of evidence. Of this, I can't see
my slides very well. Of necessity, my
answer to this question is going to be more speculative,
because this is actually a very hard issue on which to
develop systematic evidence. We can think first about what
might be called demand side developments. By that, I mean
developments that give rise to the deep political discontent
that clearly underpins rising support for populism. And then I'm going to say a
few words about what we could call supply side developments. Namely, the ways in which public
policies and party strategies impinge on this support. And my remarks are based on
a growing body of evidence, but they're going to be so brief
as to be virtually telegraphic. Thanks. So long-term economic
developments clearly matter. Nothing I'm saying here is
going to surprise anybody in this room. In particular, the
loss of secure, reasonably well paying jobs-- often, though not always
in manufacturing-- have left many people without
secure jobs or incomes. The kind of incomes on
which they could comfortably raise a family. And there's clear evidence
that those circumstances, those economic circumstances
are closely related to support for populist parties. But note that those who are
worse off in economic terms, tend to gravitate towards
parties of the radical left, while those who vote for
parties or candidates of the populist right,
tend to be a few runs up the economic or social ladder. And in some sense I think,
worried about falling farther down that ladder. And there's some
evidence that what bothers these
supporters of populism, right populism in
particular, the most, is not the immediate
economic circumstances of their household,
but rather a sense that they and their
children no longer have the opportunities that they
once thought they could expect. And they're not entirely
wrong about that. Raj Chetty's data that I've
just put up here, many of you will have seen, suggests
that the younger cohorts in this country have much
lower levels of opportunity than people who were
born when I was. So these people's
complaints are not so much about their personal
household circumstances, as they are about the direction
of society as a whole. For them, something
that we could think of as a social
contract is unraveling. Now some think that the
relevant economic developments have to do mainly with
the outsourcing that is associated with globalization. My own view is that
technological change is more important for the
economic insecurity that's central here. And that's important, because
while protectionist policies can provide some elements
of protection, if you like, against outsourcing, trying
to stop technological change is a recipe for reducing
general standards of living. So it matters what the
sources of this are. But lest we think that
populism is simply an unfortunate and inexorable
byproduct of economic progress, we should note, and I
would certainly argue, that many people's
lives have been made worse by the
neo-liberal policies pursued by Western governments, and
some non-Western governments in the past 30 years. So if the root
cause of discontent lies in the disappearance of
what I would call decent jobs, and I think it does,
we should remember that public policies
can make existing jobs more or less decent. With minimum wage
laws, with measures that facilitate or impede the
organizing of trade unions, with regulations that
impose certain obligations on firms or those
who employ workers. So I think Western governments
are reaping the fruits of what they have sown. And of course, cultural
developments also matter here, and much could be
said about that. But I'm going to allude
to them only briefly in the context of
developments on the supply side of the economy. So for 40 years after the Second
World War, partisan competition in most Western
democracies took place along a familiar
left-right axis of the sort I portray in this diagram. In which support for state
intervention and redistribution was central to the left
side and opposition to that was central to the
right side of this spectrum. I think as we all know,
beginning in the 1980s, this traditional left-right
cleavage was cross-cut by a second cleavage, often
called a values cleavage, that separates people
with a post-materialist or cosmopolitan
values from people with more traditional
values associated with conservative
religious ideas, anti-immigrant
sentiments, ethnic views of the nation and the like. And in that context, over the
course of the 1980s and '90s, electoral competition in Europe,
and I think in this country too, take place along the
diagonal of this diagram. Because center
left parties moved to support cosmopolitan values. And on the other
end, that dimension is anchored by
radical right parties espousing traditional values,
but also laissez-faire economic policies. An important point. And you'll have
noticed something interesting about this diagram. Namely, there are parties in all
three of these four quadrants. Although only a few in
the upper right quadrant. But there are no
political parties in the lower left quadrant. And there are a lot of people
in that lower left quadrant, namely people who
want to see some kind of economic protection,
but have relatively traditional and
sometimes anti-immigrant views on values issues. So over the last decade
or so, what's happened is that these radical
right parties, which have always been traditional. Not to say authoritarian
in their positions on values issues,
have moved away from their laissez-faire
positions, their low tax, small state positions
on economic issues, and begun to argue for
more redistribution, more kinds of social protection. Sometimes it's trade
protection instead of more social benefits. But it's nonetheless
a clear message. And of course, you can
see what's happened. And I think that that is
true also in this country, although I don't have time
to say much more about it I'm going to close
very quickly here. This has had two effects. First, well the other, I
suppose the other development that I want to
emphasize here, is that over the same period of
time, over the past 30 years, there's been a convergence
in the economic platforms of the center left
and the center right. To many people, the center
left and the center right looks like Tweedledum and Tweedledee. And I would argue that on
economic issues, that's true, even in the US, where
nonetheless, polarization is so widely a feature
of our political system. And that's had two effects. First, it means that many
people wonder whether anybody speaks for them. Whether the parties
are indeed simply Tweedledum and Tweedledee. And secondly, it means that
the mainstream parties, which have been so similar on economic
issues, have in an effort to distinguish themselves
from one another, shifted to emphasize values issues. And that's what this
slide indicates. And of course, by centering
political competition around values
issues, those parties have played right into the hands
of the populist right, which wins votes primarily
on values issues. So in fact, I think
we're facing something like a perfect economic
and social storm with serious consequences
for the Western democracies, as well as the developing world. And I'll look forward to
hearing more about that from the other panelists. Thanks. GERALD NEUMAN: Thank you. RUTH OKEDIJI: Thank you,
Gerry, and thank you to everyone who's here. I want to focus my
remarks building somewhat on themes that Peter
has already articulated, but locating them
in particular in the sub-Saharan African space. I find the subject both
deeply perplexing and somewhat uncomfortable when thinking
about sub-Saharan Africa in large part because
values politics is not something that has been
characteristic in most sub-Saharan African countries. Now one might say, this
is because democracies are still young and
fledgling, largely unstable. One might think that
the real issues tend to be principally economic, and
therefore, democratic values have not been deeply entrenched. And one might think
that in fact, what's going on in most of
sub-Saharan Africa is the question of how to
integrate their economies more significantly and materially
into the global economic order. I think all of those
observations are correct. But I think they
also mask something that is much more
fundamental and that has, in my view, something
that's squarely laid at the feet of
international human rights. And in particular, the reporting
and the credibility mechanisms that are associated
with norm setting in the international
human rights corpus. In my comments, in
my written comments, I highlight the fact that
international human rights law has long had an Africa problem. That Africa problem
is one that is both a problem of legitimacy,
the extent to which African leaderships in
the post-colonial state viewed international
human rights both as a source of leverage
for its anti-colonial struggle. But it was also deeply resistant
to the international human rights framework. In part, because
it was presented as a neutral set of values
that had universal appeal. And while it was politically
expedient for many countries to embrace the
Universal Declaration and certainly in the heyday
of post-colonial statehood it was accompanied quite
sharply by deep discontent and by deep resistance in some
quarters of the United Nations system. And so I start off
first by putting on the ground what I
think is really going on in the sub-Saharan
African space, where one might on
the surface say, that there have been
significant democratic wins in the last 10, 15 years. We've seen Nigeria,
for example, now pass democratic
governments twice with relatively
peaceful elections. We've seen Namibia
engage actually in e-voting for the first time. Again, a very stable transition. And then there's Kenya. And I put this picture
of the famous handshake, for those of you who've
been following what's been happening in Kenyan politics. And I start here
with what I think is part of the
consequences of what's happening in Western liberal
democracies and the spillover effects or at least the
reaction and perhaps masked effects of what's happening the
sub-Saharan African continent. So Kenya, again joining
the list of countries where democratic elections
ostensibly have been free, fair and have been
stable most importantly, as you know dubbed Raila
the people's president. The idea being
that corruption is what produced the
presidential results that brought the re-election
of the old president. And there was, of course,
deep chasm protests efforts by the people's
president to ensure that the legitimacy of
the democratic process remained in challenge. For the first time
on the continent, a judiciary ruled that
there had to be a revolt of the presidential elections. And of course, the
same outcome occurred. Raila continued to contest
the outcome of the elections, generating sufficient
angst and division by appealing in many
ways to what are, I would say, some
populist tendencies. The idea that it
is us versus them. I belong to the people. This is an educated
elite that depends on technocratic expertise
in making judgments. And of course, the economic
conditions across the continent and in Kenya as well,
continue to reveal deepening economic
divide between the haves and the have nots. And so the people's
president continue to generate significant
credibility, significant appeal. Destabilizing what
one would otherwise call a fairly fair and
transparent, at least certainly by sub-Saharan African
standards, election outcome. Kenyans went to sleep one
night and woke up the next and there was-- actually, this is poignant
because we're not sure how long the handshake will
last, so it's completely fine. But went to bed one
morning in a society that was deeply divided,
in which people who were in favor
of the opposition really felt that they had a
voice that represented who they were, their everyday struggles. These were the
ordinary people who had been left behind
by the political elite, and whose interests
and whose priorities were marginalized and
sidelined in national politics. And there was also
the sense that there was a legacy of leadership. That from father to son with a
ruling class essentially that had crystallized over the
years of independence. And that there was no way
for the average person or ordinary
politicians, in fact, to begin to represent the
people in what was essentially an iron cage of politics. And so the people of
Kenya went to bed one night, woke up the
next morning, and here was the famous handshake
that has reverberated around the continent, and in
some ways, around the world, leaving the people's
president essentially in some kind of detente
with the ruling class. What that handshake
means, I will reflect on as I go through the talk. My sense is that the sense,
the form of populism, this deep
dissatisfaction arising from political
economic insecurity, is a strange thing to associate
with populism or quasi populism in the African context,
because economic insecurity has been the status quo since the
post-colonial state emerged. I will say, however,
that there is something different about the
sense of economic anxiety that has tinged
the political class and that has stirred what
we would historically have simply referred
to as tribal interests. Now there are lots of things
that Africa cannot teach Western developed
mature democracies. But the one thing Africa
can teach is tribalism. Tribalism has long characterized
the political process. And it is very much shaped
around the sense of us versus them. The sense of superiority,
be it on racial grounds, be it on caste
grounds, be it simply as the result of
the colonial state and the way in which
power was allocated amongst different ethnic groups. But one thing about
tribalism is, it's always been a zero sum game. It has never been about
pluralistic politics. And certainly in the
1960s and the 1970s, there was an effort to try
to transform tribal politics into some form of a pluralistic
democratic process, in which representative voice
and representative vote would carry the day over and
above tribal affiliations and tribal tendencies. That has not been successful
in sub-Saharan Africa. And in fact, within the
ostensible political process, tribalism goes and
runs quite deeply in the way in which
power is shared, in the way in which
power is transferred, and in the kinds of
political institutions that in essence, make it
very difficult for claims about human rights
violations in the process to become the focal point of
international human rights institutions. So one of the
challenges, of course, is that when you have
an appeal to the kind of deep dissatisfaction arising
from political or economic isolation and insecurity,
that becomes amplified when you can tie or connect that
dissatisfaction with the ruling elites' allegiance
to neo-liberalism. And that has, of course,
been the situation in most of the African
economies in which we have seen stable transitions
of power, but we've seen the emergence of opposition
forces, opposition figures who have become heroes in the
minds of the average person or in the minds of a
significant population to demand access to
political governance. And to demand access
in particular, to the kinds of rights, economic
and social and cultural, that have long eluded
the average citizen of an African country. I think the populism
of this kind of historic tribalistic
kind of exclusionary force has long impeded the
development of what I would call a thick
corpus of human rights governing, and
shaping, and defining the way in which the African
post-colonial state has engaged in democratic governance. In fact, the emphasis of course,
in the international human rights field on
political rights, even in the face of significant
economic and developmental challenges, has not helped. In fact, it has enhanced the
sense that what is needed is not liberal policies and is
not democratic institutions, but instead, the
kind of leader that is going to simply
declare rights and the interests of his
or her political tribe. And in this case literal, his or
her linguistic and sociological tribe. And to elevate that above
adherence or allegiance to pluralism or to
international engagement. Put simply, I think that
there is room for the argument that when you look at the
way in which African leaders, especially those who are
brought before the International Criminal Court,
for example, appeal to these populist tendencies,
the argument has always been that I have kept us immune
as a country or as a people, from these foreigners. We have not in the
immigrant sense, but in the sense
of foreign agents, in the sense of
foreign expertise, international institutions
who have been part of the norm setting process, that has sought
to elevate democratic process perhaps over and above. And as I make an argument, to
the detriment of what I think is real fully grounded
and fully matured opportunities for
democracy to evolve in the pluralistic sense. So there is room, I think, for
the international human rights system to be charged
in some way as being an ally of these failed
neo-liberal policies that have characterized the kinds
of intrusive recommendations by the IMF or the World Bank or
of international institutions, that have left millions and
millions of average Africans in squalor and in deep poverty. Now, one of the things
that African states try to do in this
tension between the use of international human
rights instruments to advance independence
and sovereignty, and at the same time to
resist the sense of the other and of the foreign and
of the expert coming in to shape cultural and
normative identity, was to develop a
distinct and culturally relevant or
regionally distinctive African Charter of Human Rights. The African Charter
of Human Rights has been critiqued
and celebrated for lots of different reasons. But what I want to identify
is one consistent critique has been the claw-backs, right? The idea that African states
were limited in many ways, or could be limited in many
ways to simply recognizing and protecting human rights up
to the degree that national law allowed that too. Now, in systems where
tribalism reigns, and in systems where de facto
and de jure discrimination against members
of other minority groups or ethnic
groups was concretized by economic policies
that allowed those who did not
have access to be further distance from the
means of economic progress nationally only served, I think,
to concretize the resentment that average populations faced-- When talking about the
promises that human rights and the aspirations of
the human rights regimes. These clawbacks,
and if you think about the ways in which Mugabe's
Zimbabwe or Gambia's Jammeh were in fact used to
justify either throwing out the white farmers or
Jammeh in particular, elevating only members
of his own ethnic group in all of the elite
positions, really became a source of division in a
way that made people distrust the political
process, and made them more willing to
embrace these kinds of economic nationalist
tribal sentiments that had become a part of
the political process. Now the problem, of course,
is that the excesses of the elite political
class were not captured by human rights
monitoring or by human rights enforcement. Why? Because the emphasis
on political rights tended to elevate processes and
institutions above the material choices the governments were
making that were systematically disenfranchising
and marginalizing large areas of the populace. If you look at the
annual human rights reports, starting from
the US Department of State to Amnesty International
and Human Rights Watch, all of these have been
for the last 25, 30 years, been
singularly preoccupied with political processes
and political institutions, without recognizing the
quite embedded tribal and non pluralistic and largely
alienating tendencies that these policies were
creating and fomenting the interest in, what I would
call, a quasi populist appeal to reject anything
that looked to be consistent with a
neo-liberal order. At least in the sub-Saharan
African context, I think building human rights
initiatives and priorities around political
rights, tends to ignore the structural
conditions that are a prerequisite to the
exercise of personal liberty. And I think there are three
countries that illustrate this quite powerfully,
and that have been problematic from a human
rights perspective in thinking about how to address
the lack of interest and the lack of monitoring on
economic and social rights, and this emphasis
on political rights. So Zimbabwe I've
already mentioned, most you are familiar with
what is happening in Robert Mugabe's Zimbabwe. But what most reports have not
picked up on in the transition, in the recent transition of
the ouster of Robert Mugabe, is of course, that power was
transitioned not necessarily in consistency with a real
full-fledged robust democratic process. But rather in reaction to
Mugabe's own preference for handing power
over to someone that had already
been self-selected. So had there not be the intense,
the intense entrenchment of the ruling elite, there may
have been no one for Mugabe to hand power over to. The fact that
someone existed that was willing to
accept that power, and that the people recognized
as an inevitable heir to Mugabe's non-democratic
rulership, is in itself an ironic testament
to the way in which process and institutions
have been elevated over the substance of whether
or not democratic inclusion and pluralistic policies
are allowed to flourish within the continent. South Africa, of
course, the same thing. Angola, in fact, the same thing. It suggests that law, and
particular human rights law, and economic
inequality have long co-existed in the sub-Saharan
African continent. And that the
democratic processes that would have constrained the
kind of unlimited power grabs and the way in which
economic policies have really marginalized large
groups of people on principally
ethnic grounds, have been ignored in the emphasis
in the human rights realm, in focusing on reporting
on political rights. One final point, and
then I want to close up. And that is the way in which
human rights organizations have shaped the human
rights debate in sub-Saharan African countries. So that even domestic
non-governmental organizations and human rights
organizations have felt an inability to articulate
the cause of the deep decay of pluralistic
politics, and the way in which tribalistic politics
have become the status quo. And that is because there has
been no capacity in many ways, to report on the economic
and the financial and the corruption that
tends to accompany many of these populist campaigns. So I guess I would
wrap up by saying in terms of some
observations, my own sense is that the human
rights regimes really need to begin to
think more closely, and there needs to be
some reflection on how group and economic,
social and cultural rights might assume a more
significant role, at least in the shaping of the
global human rights agenda. To translate those
rights not only on paper, but into meaningful
institutions that allow a check and balance on
the kinds of policies that have produced the deep political
and economic insecurities and dissatisfaction,
and a legitimacy that many on the
African continent perceive of the
normal average, what we would call democratic
processes that elect leaders, but leave people
in a deep state of poverty. GERALD NEUMAN: Thank you. Matthew? MATTHEW C. STEPHENSON: Great. Thanks so much. So I think in many
ways what I have to say today is going to
be a little bit narrower, but I think very
closely related. So I'm not by any means
an expert in human rights. I generally like them and think
there should be more of them. But the main reason
that I'm here, is that my principal
research focus these days is on corruption
and anti-corruption. And Gerry and the other
conference organizers had a sense, which I
share, that corruption is a big part of the story
with respect to the rise of these populist leaders. And so in this
opening session, I wanted to try to maybe lay the
groundwork for a little bit more discussion of
how that issue factors into this other
constellation of issues, by raising a couple of questions
about this relationship between corruption and
the rise of populism. And then maybe a little bit more
indirectly, the human rights issues that are going
to be the central focus of the discussion. The first of these
questions is, you can think of it as a broad,
actually, set of questions, but I'd summarize it
by framing it this way. In what ways might corruption
or the public or rhetorical response to
corruption contribute to the rise of populism? Particularly the
more authoritarian or quasi authoritarian
versions of populism. I think that as many as are
likely aware, many-- not all, but many populist leaders-- left and right wing populists,
but I'm focusing more on the right wing populists--
have deployed the rhetoric of anti-corruption as
a significant feature of their campaigns, and
many people have attributed the emphasis on that issue-- attributed to the emphasis
on an issue, at least part of the appeal of
these populist movements. So for those of us in the United
States, Donald Trump's drain the swamp campaign slogan is
probably the most familiar, but folks like Viktor
Orban in Hungary and Rodrigo Duterte
in the Philippines and numerous others, have
talked very explicitly about corruption. Both Peter and Ruth
referenced this in their presentations, the
idea that the existing elite or the existing
government is corrupt. And that one of the
reasons to give power to these populist
leaders or movements is a sense that the
existing political elites are so thoroughly
corrupt or have so failed to solve these
deep rooted corruption problems, that the
populist alternative starts to seem more appealing. While we don't have really
good rigorous evidence testing the hypothesis that
corruption contributes to the rise of populism,
there is pretty good evidence that's suggestive of the
validity of that hypothesis. There is good
evidence, for example, that in those countries with
higher levels of corruption or perceived corruption when
you do surveys related to, though not the same
as the kind that Peter was talking about in his work-- trust in government is lower. Belief that democracy is the
right system of government is lower. Willingness to entertain
more radical alternatives to the status quo is higher,
and so on and so forth. So that may be one direct
mechanism through which corruption, especially
unchecked systemic corruption, can lay the groundwork for
a populist party or leader or movement to make headway. Another maybe indirect
channel through which corruption or failure to
check systemic corruption might contribute to
the rise of populism is the idea, again for which we
have decent, though certainly not conclusive evidence, that
systemic corruption contributes to a bunch of the other problems
that Ruth and Peter have talked about, that are often
thought to be contributors to the rise of populism. So economic inequality,
for example, seems to have broadly
speaking in the data, a correlation with corruption. The frequency of
macroeconomic crises seems to be associated
with widespread corruption. People feeling like they don't
have adequate access to health care or education, or that
their jobs are insecure, or that the only people who
can get good, stable jobs are those who are
well-connected or pay bribes, are the sorts of things that
might contribute to the appeal of populist leaders. So for this reason, there is
I think a plausible hypothesis that failing to address
systemic, entrenched corruption in a society may
lay the groundwork for the rise of these kinds of
populist leaders or movements. I'm certainly sympathetic
to that hypothesis. I think broadly speaking it's
probably true at least some of the time. But I do want to raise
a few qualifications or caveats about that
idea, that there's this kind of causal
arrow leading from unchecked corruption
to the rise of populism, especially what
you might think of is as right wing or quasi
authoritarian populism. The first point is something
I'll return to in a moment, because it's going to be related
to the second kind of question I want to pursue. But I'll raise it
here and bracket it. And that's that we need to
be careful not to assume too quickly that when populist
leaders or movements rail against the corruption
of the elite or say they're going
to drain the swamp and deal with a society's
corruption problem, they mean by
corruption what people like me, who study this
in an academic sense, mean by corruption. I think when I was listening
to Peter's presentation, when he was talking about how
populist parties, especially in Western Europe and
the United States, are railing against the
corruption of the elites, it's not clear that they
mean bribery and embezzlement and things of that sort. There's is a different
broader sense of corruption. So I think that we need
to be careful to be sensitive to the
fact that the word corruption means
many different things in many different contexts. And the appeal of a kind of
drain the swamp slogan might not actually be
because people are worried that bribery, and
nepotism, and embezzlement are extensive. That might be a kind
of political code word for a different
sense of corruption. Second thing, it's
an important caveat, is that while I think
there's a plausible case to be made that failure to
really deal with and root out systemic corruption, especially
in some of the developing countries of the sort that
Ruth was emphasizing more in her presentation,
may contribute to the rise of these
dangerous populist movements-- There's a concern that
under some circumstances, aggressive anti-corruption
efforts may themselves lay the groundwork for the rise
of insurgent populist parties. And this can occur in a couple
of ways that are distinct, but nonetheless related. The first is that the exposure
of widespread corruption through media investigations
or prosecutions can, under some
circumstances, end up discrediting the political
establishment across the board. So these investigations,
we think they're good, they're exposing corruption,
but under certain circumstances actually, it makes
people even more cynical about the existing
political class. Makes them even more
open to the idea that some kind of outsider
with no political background or history is the way to go. The second thing that
can sometimes happen is at least in extreme cases,
anti-corruption investigations and prosecutions have caused the
collapse, the entire collapse of major political
parties, sometimes multiple political
parties, leaving a power vacuum into which
charismatic figures can enter. So I think Italy in
the 1990s is probably the lead example of this
sort of thing happening, where the so-called tangentopoli
or Clean Hands investigation, did a couple of things. One is, it caused
essentially the collapse in Italy of the center
left and the center right. Because they had
been governing Italy since basically the end
of the Second World War, particularly the center right,
and the exposure of corruption in those parties
was so widespread, the parties basically
ceased to exist. Which, and it also
substantially increased the cynicism of
many Italian voters about the political
class generally. And I'm not an expert
in Italy, but I've spoken to people who are,
and there is the argument that this is one of the
things that opened the field for someone like Berlusconi. Because the traditional
parties were gone, he was perceived as this
incredibly successful businessman, very charismatic
and ran very much as I'm an outsider who's different. Now of course, I'll get to this
more a little bit in a moment. Berlusconi himself, is not
exactly a paragon of integrity. But there was
something about the way in which this root
and branch demolition of the traditional
political parties to an anti-corruption
investigation created a dangerous
power vacuum. Brazil actually right
now is the country where I'm most worried
about this replicating. The parallels, I think again, as
an outsider to both countries, between the so-called
Lava Jato or Car Wash investigation in Brazil,
and the Clean Hands investigation in Italy
are eerie in many ways. And there is a concern,
at least I have, that this I think in many
ways really much needed and to some degree,
heroic effort that Brazilian prosecutors
and judges are undertaking to root out corruption in Brazil
could, if the right steps are not taken, create
the kind of openings for a Berlusconi-like
figure or worse. And I gather we're
already seeing evidence that this is happening. So that's, I think an important
qualification or caveat to the idea that if
you only root out corruption, then
of course, you'll dampen the appeal of populists. Another consideration I
want to put on the table, it's a little bit
different, but I feel like it's worth
raising, especially when you consider countries
like the ones Peter was focusing on a bit more and
the ones Ruth was focusing on. And it has to do less with the
actual legal or policy response to traditional corruption,
than the language or rhetoric that people,
including people, like people in this room, the civil
society community, academics, journalists,
commentators and others use to describe the failings
of a political system. Whether it's the excessive
influence of special interest groups and money in politics
or various other kinds of systematic unfairness. And let me lay
out the question I want to raise by articulating
two hypotheses about the 2016 election and surrounding events. And they go like this. Hypothesis number one
is that the United States is at the very
least a plutocracy, if not a kleptocracy. It's fair to characterize
its institutions as those that are systemically
corrupt in a variety of ways. Not through illegal
corruption necessarily, like bribery or embezzlement,
but through all sorts of ways that those who are wealthy
or powerful or otherwise, are able to manipulate the
system for their own ends. But, the argument continues, the
traditional mainstream parties were reluctant to use the
language of corruption to describe the failings
of the US political system. And this created the space
on the left for candidates like Bernie Sanders, and
on the right for candidates like Donald Trump to
seize that terrain, to use that rhetoric
that would resonate with many American
voters to call to call the system corrupt. On this view, the great
failing of the elite, the establishment,
the mainstream, whatever you want to call
it, was the reluctance to use the rhetoric
of corruption to describe the systemic
failings of the US political system. So this is an argument
articulated by our law school colleague, Larry Lessig. It's been advanced by the
former journalist, now writer and researcher, Sarah
Chayes, that have made that argument quite explicitly. And it is certainly
a plausible argument. The alternative
argument, though, is that this
position, though I'll call the Lessig-Chayes position,
has it exactly backwards. And that the real problem was
the overuse of scorched earth rhetoric to describe the very
real and genuine failings of the US political system in
ways that inadvertently managed to discredit that establishment
conventional way of doing things. So the tendency to describe
every policy failure as the result of
the shadowy cabal of special interests, the
Tweedle Dum, Tweedle Dee language. I think I'd actually take
issue here with Peter's point that the two major parties
in the US and Western Europe really are on economic
policy, basically the same. But that idea that there's
no difference between the two major parties because
they're all neo-liberals have been captured by corporations-- the idea that just
the kind of what I think of as the sort
of fashionable cynicism of, oh, they're all a bunch of
crooks and liars and corrupt. This is the argument. That it wasn't the under-use
of the rhetoric of corruption to describe the failings
of the system that opened the door for
politicians like Trump, it was the overuse
of that rhetoric and the de-legitimization
of the kind of boring, dull, un-sexy
kind of politics. That it's about
incrementalism and coalition building, and differences
in policy agendas, and so forth that
made it seem much more appealing to have someone who's
just going to come in and blow the whole system up. So I'll close this
part of my talk, and I don't have
that much time left. I do have one more
question I want to address. But the underlying
dilemma as I see it, is corruption
itself can undermine the legitimacy of the
political establishment, thereby opening the door
to an insurgent populist. But at the same time,
attempt to attack corruption, whether it's
through actual prosecutions or through the use
of strong rhetoric to describe the existing
system, can also under some circumstances,
discredit the establishment and open the door to
insurgent populists. And I think a challenge
is figuring out how to navigate that dilemma. The second question, which
I realize I have less time, but I'll try to get
it across quickly, it has to do less with
the rise of populism, and what happens once the
populist movement or leader gets into power. I don't think it would be a
terribly surprising observation to anyone in this room, that
many of these populist leaders, whether or not
they ran on a drain the swamp kind of
platform, are not exactly paragons of integrity. Whether you're talking about
Berlusconi in Italy or Orban in Hungary or Thaksin in
Thailand or the Kirchners in Argentina or Donald
Trump in the United States, very often you see these people
engage in really substantial corruption of their own. Which raises a puzzle-- why doesn't this behavior
alienate the supporters of the populist movement more? If what they're
really upset about, as this is the point
that Peter alluded to, is the idea that a
well-connected, entrenched elite is unfairly benefiting
without exhibiting the virtues of hard
work and so forth, and the system is rigged,
why isn't the Kirchners or Thaksin or Trump
benefiting their families and their cronies the ultimate
expression of that corruption that the populists are
allegedly really upset about? And also, you see in opinion
polls over and over again, people say they really
don't like corruption, it's really bad. So what's going on? If at least part of the
appeal of the populist is the opposition to
this kind of corruption, once they win office and
we see this behavior, why don't they seem to lose
that much support at least in the short to medium term? And I don't know
the answer, but let me throw out a few hypotheses. And again, countries
may vary, as Peter and Ruth both emphasize. So I'm not, no pretense
of anything universal. But a few possibilities. One is that, well, maybe
and this is the point that I alluded to before,
the rhetoric of corruption or anti-corruption wasn't
really what the populists were appealing to. They weren't appealing to
a worry about corruption in the conventional form. Corruption was
being used as a kind of code word for effete
cosmopolitan snobs, and Jews, and immigrants taking your
jobs, or depriving you of your rightful
place in society, or the social status to which
you think you are entitled. It didn't really have to do with
giving contracts to friends, and hiring relatives,
or taking bribes. I think that's
certainly possible. I think another possibility is
that even though voters don't like corruption, many
voters, including the ones to whom the
populists appeal most strongly, if there's
one thing they dislike more than corruption,
it's moralistic scolds. And I think one of the things
we sometimes see in these cases, again Italy is I think
a useful example here, but there are others as well. When elites like us go on
and on about the corruption of this leader, it is
sometimes perceived as holier than thou, self-righteous,
moralistic scolding, which people resent. And they might resent it as
well, if they themselves, have occasionally bent
or broken the rules. They might experience
these attacks on the leader for the leader's
lack of integrity as attacks on them from a group of
people who often they perceive as don't even
have the standing to raise those kinds of concerns. So again, in Italy the
attacks of the Italian left, the Communist Party in
particular on Berlusconi, were often greeted as
sanctimonious and hypocritical. Some have taken this
one step further and suggested that one of
the tricks that at least some of these populist leaders
managed to pull off is what you might term
for lack of better words, the politics of absolution. That is, in societies where
corruption is pervasive, and a lot of people
have done stuff that's technically against the
rules, what the more skillful of these populist
leaders manage to do is establish kind of
implicit mutual forgiveness. To tell the people,
you guys are great. Everyone is always
telling you you're bad, that our
society is terrible, but you guys are great. And just do what you want to do. And the implicit bargain is I
forgive you and you forgive me. Right? You steal a little
bit, I steal a lot, but we're kind of
on the same team. Maybe related to that too,
is that even though people say don't like corruption,
they might in some perverse way admire the charismatic
populist leader who seems to be living
the kind of life that they wish they could
lead, if only they could. Again, to come back
to Italy, there's apparently a lot of evidence
that Italian voters thought that a lot of what Berlusconi
did and a lot of the way he behaved, including
all of his mistresses, was at least to Italian men,
considered like, wow, he's living the dream. And apparently Trump
has a similar appeal with many Americans. And it relates to
the earlier point that sometimes the
more one criticizes the vulgarity, and
the lack of integrity and so on and so forth,
it can end up leading to this dynamic where
people who actually identify with that person experience
these attacks as attacks on them. Saying that they're
bad people, too. And it does seem to be,
though, this strange paradox-- and I don't have
the answer, but I hope it will be part of our
conversation going forward-- where voters generally,
and the supporters of populist movements
in particular, will tell you that they care
deeply about corruption, that one of the
real reasons they're drawn to these
outsiders is the feeling that they have to do
something to clean up the systemic corruption
of the system. But they don't
seem to be bothered by what seems like pretty
clear and convincing evidence of drastic corruption by
these leaders themselves. And it's a real puzzle
about how these shysters are able to pull it off. And I hope we can maybe
make some progress in figuring out why that is. GERALD NEUMAN: Thank you. Our panelists have given
us a lot think about, and now I would like to include
the people in the discussion. Can I ask, are there people on
the floor who'd like to speak? I'd like to remind
you that this event is being recorded, so
don't speak if you don't wish to be recorded. If you, could I please ask
you to ask an actual question and to keep your remarks
within certain brevity and to identify yourselves
when your take the floor. Or I'll identify you. Richard. AUDIENCE: I want to just
build on Matthew's point on the issue of once you
open an anti-corruption kind of campaign, that actually
could open up the insurgency. And I think that
perfectly happened in the case of the Philippines,
with Aquino's opening up the investigation,
and in the process discrediting the whole system. But looking at the populist art
of governance with the Duterte already in a
position of power, I think the other thing
we have to look at is the fact that how
they can effectively deploy conspiracy theory. They say that whenever
you expose corruption within the populist
administration, they'll say that this is just
a conspiracy of the regime to bring us down. And the other way of also people
justifying this is saying, well, they're under
siege, so they have to bribe other
people in order to protect their projects. So I thought maybe
that's another aspect that we could look at, and
I think is relevant to Italy and other countries too. RUTH OKEDIJI: Well, I was
just going to say something about that, and this is
really Matthew's point, but I think that's
really important. But that goes back to the
point about legitimacy. By the time you see
populist insurgents come up, there's already the
scorched earth tactics. Over the course of time there
has been this gradual erosion of faith and trust fueled
by economic inequality, fueled by a sense of
isolation, as Peter mentioned. Fueled by all sorts
of different things. And this is the essence,
really, of tribalism. It's the idea that if
we don't save ourselves, nobody will save us. Right? And so once you lose legitimacy
it doesn't matter how much you expose corruption,
because the answer will be you're just trying to
get rid of someone who's going to take care
of our interests, and therefore we
don't believe you. Reinforcing as Matthew says,
the power and, in fact, the credibility of
the populist regime. MATTHEW C. STEPHENSON: Yeah. I mean, definitely. The phenomenon you point
out happens all the time. I mean, Ruth probably
could have talked about this at much
greater length, because several of the
specific examples that she used in her presentation, and
also discussed in her paper, fit this perfectly. Robert Mugabe was
like, the maestro of the conspiracy theory. Everything was being
engineered by the CIA. Jacob Zuma in South
Africa, though complicated the situation as the same
kind of populist leader, also, every time corruption
was exposed, was saying this
is all a CIA plot. Right? That was his line. So a couple of
things about that-- one is that maybe slightly
more encouragingly-- I was speaking to an expert
in South African politics at a conference not too
different from this one back in the fall, who
suggested at least the Zuma example suggests that
over time, this stops working. That it worked really well
the first couple of times that Zuma deployed it,
and then after a while, eventually he was
forced to resign, it started losing its traction. The second thing,
and I think this relates very much to your
point and some of the larger discussion, there is no
Archimedean neutral point in politics. But at the same time
in certain polities, it seems like there
are some institutions, whether formal or informal,
that are more trusted. Or at least a
cluster of them are trusted to give some
version of the truth. So in South Africa, the Office
of the Public Protector, at least when Thuli
Madonsela was running it, kind of had that credibility,
and was a counterweight to Zuma, even though
she didn't have that much in the way
of institutional power. Still, I think she had
enough credibility. One of the concerns
is that when you lose those independent voices,
precisely the phenomenon you describe can take place. And I think this
is to your point, the populists will try to
undermine and discredit those-- so everything is
fake news, right? And again, in this
country we go for 30 years where people generally,
but particularly one political faction has
been talking about media bias over and over and over again,
to the point where people might be more receptive now to the
claim that anything you hear that's negative about
your guy is actually the product of fake news, or
conspiracy, or propaganda. I think you actually
see this in Israel right now where,
again, Netanyahu-- not a populist, necessarily the
sort that we're talking about, but he and his supporters
are very clearly trying to do things to
discredit the police. Which in Israel, has
traditionally been a very independent institution. More independent, independent
from the attorney general and that cabinet. And to make various
legal and other changes to discredit the significance
of the police recommendations that Netanyahu and his
associates be indicted. Right? So I think the point, I'm really
glad you raised the point, because I think
this is critical, and it actually goes to
one of the issues I read. Why don't people care
about corruption? Well, if they don't believe
that it exists or everything is a plot, then it's
not going to have the same kind of impact. GERALD NEUMAN:
Peter, can I ask-- do you want to respond
to what's just been said? Or-- PETER A. HALL: Not yet. GERALD NEUMAN: To any of what
Ruth and Matthew have said? PETER A. HALL: No. GERALD NEUMAN: Or later? PETER A. HALL: No,
other than to say it's been very interesting so far. [LAUGHTER] GERALD NEUMAN:
Note the qualifier. So far. In the back. I can't quite see you. AUDIENCE: Thank you so much. Excellent presentations,
all of you. I'm just curious
to know, the role of these disenfranchised groups. You're talking about the
Palestinians and the Israelis, you're talking about
blacks, Latinos and here, the concept of building
a wall to keep them away, and how does that play out? It seems like we're going,
instead of corruption, it seems like you're
getting more traction by really isolating these
groups and really throwing the weight of the
state, so to speak, or the weight of the
power against this group to get the populace
involved in the process, and getting to rally
on your behalf. And I wonder, and you see that
obviously in Germany and now here, is really very strong. And I wonder how
you in the formulas you involve corruption and
a lot of other factors, these groups have
to do with race in the spectrum of these
populous figure coming up? PETER A. HALL: OK, there's
nothing I can speak to. So I quite agree with you. I think that while Matt has
made a totally convincing case that issues of corruption
are important here, certainly in the European
countries I look at, and I would have said
in this country too, it's the ethno-nationalist
character of the appeal that it is in some
ways the best candidate to be the central
feature of these parties. And indeed, the studies
do show that if you look at what's set of attitudes
are most commonly and strongly associated with support
for populist right parties, then anti-immigration
sentiment is the attitude that comes out most
strongly in those estimations. Now but what that is exactly
and where it comes from is, I think, still something
of a puzzle for us. And there seem to be a number
of different things going on. I again, I'll try,
I'll be brief, but let me just say
something about that. So to some extent, this seems
to be a genuine response to rising rates of immigration. Which has been a dimension of
globalization, and in some ways that's why I think globalization
is such a powerful trope for the radical right. Because it has multiple
dimensions, and they can be seen as a negative. So in a country like Germany,
and I think also in Italy, if we think about
the last election, I think there's no doubt
that a concern about rising rates of immigration
plays a role in support for the populist right parties. On the other hand,
as I'm sure you know, if you were to look across
the regions of Europe and look for an association
between the number of immigrants in that region
and a right populist support, you would find no association. In fact, it's the areas
of the UK with the largest numbers of immigrants who were
most likely to vote to remain in the European Union. And of course, you can see
why that would be the case. There's a way in which
familiarity shifts people's views about the other. So the fear of
immigration in Europe is strongest in the
regions and the localities with the fewest immigrants. There's a way in
which immigration is a specter associated
with a certain kind of fear. And so that suggests
that in addition to this one kind
of channel, which has to do with a direct
response to contact with rising rates of immigration,
there may well be something else
going on which has to do with the way in which, as
many psychologists would argue, increasing economic insecurity
tends to generate resentment against outgroups. It tends to lead people to
look for outgroups, people of other races and
religions, and immigrants are the natural
candidates for that. And of course, this is exploited
by populist right parties. And so there's a kind
of endogenous effect in which, you know,
if you look back at British electoral
surveys, you'll find lots of
anti-immigrant sentiment among the ordinary British
working class people into the early '60s,
which is the earliest we have these surveys for. So there is also an element
of this being activated. So yes, I think you're right. And I think that there are some
really interesting dynamics we're only beginning
to understand there. GERALD NEUMAN: If I could just
abuse the position of the chair for a moment, and ask Peter
as a follow-up to that, in discussing populism as an
issue about the relationship between-- PETER A. HALL: Can you-- is your mic on? Can people hear? GERALD NEUMAN: I
think my mic is on. Maybe my mic is not
close enough to my mouth. In discussing
populism as involving a relationship of
critique against elites, the role of immigrants
and immigration is if I understand it, as an
unaddressed problem as to which the political elites have
been corrupt or incompetent, rather than the immigrants
themselves being viewed as the elites against
which the populist charge is directed. Or am I not under-- How should that
be thought about? PETER A. HALL: My reading
of the evidence, which is, I haven't
contributed to this, but I've read a fair
bit of it, would be no. The, I hate to break it
to you, but the resentment of immigrants is a
resentment of immigrants, not just a resentment of elites
for allowing in immigrants. You know, there are
strongly prejudicial views. There's probably a little
bit of both, right? But in the surveys
that I look at, it's people who talk
about not wanting to have a Muslim as
a neighbor or not thinking that there
should be any more just religious displays
and the like, who are most likely to be strong
supporters of populist right parties. So I think that in some
ways, it would be much easier to deal with if
this were ultimately a critique of the immigration
policies of elites. I will say for this group,
the human rights group, that I think that this
issue, the centrality of the immigration
issue here, certainly in the developed democracies
I look at, poses in some ways the most fundamental
political dilemma for those who are committed
to human rights and political progressives,
in particular. How should they be responding? Should progressive
center left parties be responding to very
significant levels of concern about immigration
by cutting back on immigration? And I think the issue's become
even more difficult when we think it's not just a
matter of closing the borders, it's also a matter of how you
treat religious minorities inside countries like
France or Germany or Austria, for instance. And there are
serious issues there, which I think can't
be totally resolved by simply saying,
well, of course, we have to defend the
cosmopolitan values and the human rights values that
we think are the most important in the world. Because there's a possibility
that if you do that, you won't be on the
political scene anymore. And there won't be anybody
to defend those values. So it is a genuine
dilemma, as opposed to something easily resolved. GERALD NEUMAN: I'd
just like to clarify that what I'm meant
to be asking was not about the social phenomenon,
but about the understanding of populism. And to the extent
in which elites are treated as a key element
in the definition of populism. PETER A. HALL: Oh, I see. Yes, well, you're right. GERALD NEUMAN:
Identifying the elites, it's the incumbent
elites who are not dealing with the immigrants
who are seen as the problem. That's the, that's how that
maps on to that definition of populism. PETER A. HALL: Yes, I think so. GERALD NEUMAN: Michael. PETER A. HALL: Sorry. GERALD NEUMAN: Sorry
for the inclarity in my phrasing of the question. Michael Posner. AUDIENCE: Hi, yeah,
Mike Posner from NYU. Peter, when you
spoke initially, you talked about demand
side and supply side. And on the demand
side, one of the things you said, at least
this is what I heard is, a big
part or an element in addition to
the anti-immigrant and issues you just
described, a big part is that there are a significant
number of people who are economically in trouble. And they're anxious about
their own personal situation. And then you said
on the supply side, liberal democratic parties
or liberal left parties have in a sense ceded the
ground on that discussion and are talking about values. And that's worked to
their disadvantage. I am interested in
knowing, are there in any countries
you've looked at, are there examples of where
center left parties have taken on the economic
issues and rather than just saying we're
sorry about it, come up with an affirmative
agenda that says here's how we would deal with it, which
is better than the other side? To what extent in any
situation have you seen a successful response
to that phenomenon? PETER A. HALL: I can't think
of great success stories. It's a great, it's a
very good question. I should have an answer
for you that I don't have. I will say that I think
it's not as if there are no differences between
center left and center right in these countries,
including in the US, as Matt said. But those differences
in recent decades have had to do mainly with
levels of social benefits. And if we took the view that
many conventional economists take of populism,
some economists take of populism,
which is that it's a revolt against globalization,
and the root cause was a failure to compensate
the losers in the context of free trade agreements. And so in some
sense, compensating the losers, the economic
losers, is the solution to this, if that means social
benefits, then I think that that's
a missed diagnosis. You have to decide whether
you see this as a response to your question or
just me rabbiting on. But because it's not, I don't
think it's social benefits that these people mainly want. And I don't think that's at
the root cause of the problem. I think the root
cause of the problem is what I call decent jobs. A capacity to have a job
that pays well enough and has enough security
that you can support a family comfortably on it. And you can look forward with
a certain amount of optimism towards your future. And the reason I'm
emphasizing this and why I think it's germane
to your question is, if we could solve this
with more social benefits, this political problem
could be solved. But all you have to
do is look at France, which has more than
50% of GDP runs through government revenue,
and there are very significant social benefits. Or look at Denmark
or Sweden, where there are also very
generous welfare states, but there are also significant
populist right parties. It's clear that social benefits,
redistribution of the sort the center left has
been willing to do, while desirable in
itself in my view, is not an answer
to this problem. And that is a real challenge. Because if the
problem is to create decent jobs in the context of a
dramatically changing economy, So. For that, that's
why I think, I guess to take it back to why this is
an answer or response anyway to your question, that's why I
think I can't think of center left governments
that have effectively responded to this issue. Because it is so
difficult to address. MATTHEW C. STEPHENSON:
Can I maybe, a couple of quick additions to that? I'm not sure I would necessarily
be quite as pessimistic in so far as one could view those
countries where the right wing populists haven't taken over, as
countries where the center left or perhaps center right, has
been successful, by virtue of the fact that they've
designed a package of policies that keeps enough
people happy, given their electoral system
that the insurgent populists haven't taken over. So again, I think it depends
on exactly what you're asking. If you're asking, places
where the populists have taken over and then beaten
back, that's one thing. But again, there, it's a
fairly recent phenomenon. If the question is, are
there countries where the populists haven't been
able to get a foothold and take over in
the first place, arguably because
the political elite has done a good enough job in
keeping enough people happy, then I think we got a lot
of examples of that, right? But that's the optimistic. The pessimistic bit of
this actually comes out of Peter's paper, so he
could have said it too. But since he
didn't, I think it's a point that he makes that's
a really good one that's worth making. In many areas of politics we
talk about an absolute welfare, but then also relative
or positional welfare. And the former, in the former
case, you can get win-win. You don't always. Sometimes we don't compensate
the losers, and that's bad. But at least with
respect to globalization, the economist would
say it would be possible with the right
package of policies to have globalization,
free trade and so forth, and make everybody better
off or at least no worse off. Because if you're
increasing net social wealth if you do the
right thing and you have the right kind
of redistribution, you can solve that problem. But if what's going on
is a positional issue, then everybody could
be getting better off in an absolute sense, but
certain people or groups are worse off in a relative
or positional sense. And they're still
going to be mad. So it was really,
I thought it was really great about Peter's paper
and the graph that he showed, is when people in different
demographic groups were asked to say where they
were on the social status ladder, it's not clear exactly
from the way the question is phrased whether it's
meant to be a relative or an absolute amount. But my conjecture is that most
people interpret it at least implicitly, as relative. So they're thinking like,
relative to where I was or where I think I should
be, this is where I am. And that's harder, because
that's kind of zero sum. You can't raise the status of,
the relative status of women and marginalized groups, to go
back to the previous question, other groups, without
decreasing the relative status of traditionally
privileged groups. And if you believe,
as some people do, that people tend to fight harder
about keeping what they have, or get angrier if they feel like
they're losing what they have, then the people on
the opposite side are made happy by getting
something that didn't have, then this might create a kind
of psychological political asymmetry. And so I would say, the
optimist in me says hey, actually most
liberal democracies in the Western world
have beaten back the populist onslaught so far. But then the pessimist
in me says, yeah, but if we want all these
things and I think a lot of us in this group want, which is
more equality, more opportunity and greater solicitude
for the interests of marginalized groups,
that will inevitably threaten the relative
position of traditionally privileged groups. And they're going to
get angry about it. And it's not clear
there's anything we can do about that at that level. RUTH OKEDIJI: If I could-- PETER A. HALL: Totally. Go ahead, Ruth. RUTH OKEDIJI: I was
just going to say, because I'd love to hear
what you have to say, because I think that Matt's
correct, plus one more thing. And that is the
values root, right? Because no matter how much
you prove absolute welfare, if the issue that's
driving is values-related, we're not going to appease
those sorts of, I think, considerations. But it's also why I say in my
paper that I'm, two things. One, I'm really concerned
first that the attack on globalization masks what
we are not doing in the United States with respect to social
economic and collective rights. Access to education, just
basic access to a decent job. We have not invested in the
structural conditions that would make it possible
for future generations to have the expectations that
our generation had, perhaps in lesser quality, but-- and
that previous generations have. And the expectation that
we should be doing better is the expectation
every American has. This is sort of the heart
of the American dream. And when people think that
their progress is stalled, even if they're better off
than they were yesterday, if they're not as well off as
they think they ought to be, there will be resentment. And we've got to deal with
that values piece of this, and deal with the reality
that if you got rid of globalization,
it would become very evident that the real
culprit is our own failure to have invested in the
kinds of conditions that make economic
well-being available and expected for every citizen. PETER A. HALL: Is there
time to say something? So I entirely agree with
what you just said, Ruth. And Matt, I'm extremely glad you
said what you said, because I entirely disagree with it. MATTHEW C. STEPHENSON: OK. PETER A. HALL: So
you're, in principle, the point is well taken. We should be thinking
about positional goods and this issue of relative
versus absolute well-being. I think your motivation
is much to be admired. And the substance I
entirely disagree with. Because I think that there's no
reason why, well so, some years ago I tried to draw,
I won't take time to try to explain how,
graphs of the status hierarchy in various
Western societies. So it can be more steep. That is, say people at the
bottom of the hierarchy, which basically, this was
taking income deciles and looking at the status
people assign themselves, the average status
in those deciles. So as you might
expect in the US, the status hierarchy
is relatively steep. But as you might expect, the
status hierarchy in Sweden is relatively flat. The status hierarchy
proved to be steeper, these measures measure
were not perfect, but broadly speaking,
the status hierarchy was steeper in Germany. There was a, but the status
hierarchy in Germany, if it was as steep as the
US, everybody in Germany thought of themselves as having
higher status than everybody in the US sort of thing. I don't have those figures here. So my point is that yes, we can
think up status in the same way that we can think of income
as being on a distribution. And there are going to be
people who are at the bottom, and they are going to
be people at the top. But those distributions
can nonetheless be, broadly speaking, more
equal or less equal. And I think that while
we could have a longer debate about this,
and I'm trying to produce a little bit
of spark to end the panel, and I would ultimately
concede that there's evidence that people care
about their relative positions. But there is some empirical
evidence, as you know, for that. Broadly speaking,
though, I think that you can improve
the situation of the middle and
even the bottom, without necessarily making
so many people at the top feel like they're the
real losers from this. And more importantly,
I think you can improve the situation
of people at the bottom without making
people in the middle feel that they are
necessarily losers. Precisely because this
distribution of status is variable. I didn't put that
very well, but-- MATTHEW C. STEPHENSON:
I would be thrilled to be wrong about that. So I hope you're right. PETER A. HALL: OK. GERALD NEUMAN: Well, we're now
at a point of reaching a zero sum game between
discussion and coffee, and I think coffee should win. So please join me in
thanking the panelists. Discussion will
continue after coffee. [APPLAUSE]