This graph shows that while in the 1980s
China's and India's economies started at roughly the same size. China soon left India in the dust,
becoming roughly five times its size. However, now, with China's economy
slowing down and Western companies
seeking to move their factories elsewhere. Could it be that it is now India's
turn to replicate China's growth miracle? That is the question
that has been keeping up both India and the world lately. However, to avoid cliche answers
like it needs to reduce corruption, liberalize its economy even more,
or increase education and infrastructure. In this video, I've turned to
two of India's most eminent economists its central bank president,
Professor Raghuram Rajan and Johns Hopkins Professor Davesh Kapur, and summarized
their vast bodies of research into key insights
about exactly one why China's economy took off after the liberal reforms
of the 80s and 90s. While India did not. Why China's growth
path will never work for India. And finally, whether or not India will soon be able
to pull off its own growth miracle. And I'm happy to report that in their research,
I found some really surprising insights about how India's real problem is
not that it didn't know what to do, but rather that it failed
to properly implement China's strategy due to its own unique political structure,
in which understaffed local governments often cater to local interests
rather than to the public, a structure that means that while there are other
growth models for India to follow, the country could not
and still can never grow like China. But to see why that is the case, we first need to answer why
China outgrew India in the first place. In other words, what caused this
massive divergence between India and China in the 1990s
and early 2000? To answer that question, I first
turned to the work of Professor Raghuram Rajan, who has highlighted
that already in the late 1970s, Chinese workers
had a better level of basic education than their Indian counterparts,
a better level of basic education enables two key elements of how China
transitioned from an agricultural society to the manufacturing powerhouse
that it is today. The first element is that to supercharge
economic growth, China started attracting a lot of foreign factories in the 80s
and 90s, factories that typically required at least a basic education from
their workers so that they could follow simple instructions. The second element is that a basic
education, especially in accounting, enabled a lot of these workers to then
later start their own companies, which propelled China's economy
to the next level in the 2000s. But given that
there were plenty of countries with a better level of basic education
in China in the late 1970s, better education alone cannot explain
why China was able to attract foreign factories and enable its workers
to start their own factories. Well, India was not. Indeed, as I discussed in my video
about China's economic miracle. Besides being able to attract foreign factories to learn from them,
there are two other key ingredients that allowed China
to transform its economy into the manufacturing superpower
that it is today. The first and most often discussed
ingredient is that in the 1980s, communist China liberalized its economy
both by allowing private entrepreneurs to start companies and by allowing
foreign firms to come into China. In my opinion,
this was indeed a necessary condition for the Chinese economic
miracle to happen. But given that there are plenty of more,
liberalized economies cannot explain China's
rapid growth by itself. India is a prime example of that. Following China, India also carefully liberalized
its socialist economy in the 1990s, and this was then followed by more
radical liberalization in the 2000. But while India's economy certainly
grew faster after these reforms, it never quite reached China's
double digit growth numbers. Of course, you could then argue that India just didn't
liberalize enough, and that may be true, but China is also still
a highly restrictive place to do business today, scoring very similar points
to India when we compare the two countries, for example,
using the Index of Economic Freedom. Therefore, to explain this massive
divergence between the two countries, I believe that we need to talk
about the second and third ingredient of the Chinese growth
miracle ingredients that India was never able to reproduce
despite the best intentions. Okay, the second key
ingredient of the Chinese growth miracle is that it followed
what Peking University professor Michael Pettis calls the investment
led growth model. This is the growth model that was at
the heart of miracle growth in countries like the United States, Germany and Japan
and then was later adopted by China. Essentially, the idea of investment
led growth is that in poor countries like China and India in the 1980s,
they have a huge underinvestment problem while they have a population
that could potentially be very productive. They are held back by a lack of infrastructure, knowledge
and productive assets such as machinery. So to grow at a miracle level speed,
a poor country simply needs to invest at miracle level speed in infrastructure
and other productive assets. But where does that money come from? You know, in a poor country,
perhaps surprisingly for a non economist, a lack of money in even the poorest
countries is never the real problem. After all, in a fiat money system,
local money is infinitely available since a central bank can just print
as much as it likes and use that money to spur unemployed workers into action. However, because the central government
of these massive countries alone cannot really hope to spend all of that
money productively to prevent inflation, they have essentially outsourced
most money creation to commercial banks who create money as debt, that money
that will not produce inflation and will not increase debt to GDP
as long as it is used to grow the economy. So to make sure that China's banks
invest in productive infrastructure and factories, China ordered its local
and state owned banks to direct credit, mostly to infrastructure
and manufacturing. Other low interest rates. And while these state interventions
can now explain why China has too much infrastructure
and even too much factory capacity, it worked extremely well when China
was still a developing country. But what about India? Why didn't India try
to follow the investment led growth model and supercharge investments
in factories and infrastructure? Well, actually it did well. It liberalized its corporate sector. It kept its banking system largely
in the hands of the state, just like China and just like China. That banking system then went on a lending spree
to well-connected business tycoons. However, unlike China's
successful entrepreneurs, India's well-connected tycoons
did not spend the money productively, which meant that around 2013,
while China's corporates increasingly conquered the world,
India's corporates were failing and heavily indebted to a state's
banking system that was close to collapse. Although I have to say that since then,
India's investment has gotten much better. A recovery that was partially made
possible by Professor Rajan himself, who as head of India's central bank,
helped clean up a lot of these bad debts. A lot of credit also goes to Modi,
who has since coming to power in 2014, made a lot of new investments
in India's infrastructure. But while Indian investment
and growth has not been bad at all, it has not been as miraculous
as that of China. Therefore, I think it's now time
that we revisit the third key ingredient of China's growth
miracle attracting foreign factories, which is also known as attracting foreign
direct investment or FDI for short. FDI gets its name from the fact that if you build a factory somewhere,
you are directly investing there. When it comes to FDI, while China became
the factory of the world, India simply failed to attract anywhere
close to the same amount of FDI. But why is it attracting FDI so important and why was China able to do it
while India failed miserably? To answer these questions, let's
go back to India and China in the 1980s. They were not just like infrastructure
and machines. They were also lacking the knowledge
about how efficient factories operate. Knowledge that you cannot learn in school. Knowledge that you instead accumulate
by working in efficient factories. This is why attracting foreign factories
to turbocharge local knowledge was the third key
ingredient for China's growth. Miracle. On top of that,
while local money is in theory infinite as it can be created by local banks
and central banks, foreign money U.S. dollars is needed for crucial imports,
such as, in China's case, German machines. So attracting foreign direct
investment is a key ingredient of most growth miracles, because it can be
used to supercharge local knowledge and to obtain the US
dollars needed for crucial imports. And as we've discussed,
China's basic education really helped
create the right environment for FDI. But according to Professor Rajan,
there's actually a deeper difference between China and India, and that is how
well their local governments function. You see, because both the Chinese
and Indian economies are decentralized systems on a massive
and I mean massive scale. It's really important to note
that getting education, investment and FDI right is really not something
that is determined at the top. You need government at the local level
to actually implement these changes, and for that
they need the right incentives. And if we zoom in to how China's
local governments work, we can see that
they had the right incentives to stimulate both local investment
and foreign direct investment. First of all, local governments were
all part of the Chinese Communist Party, and they would be promoted or demoted,
not based on how well like they were by the local population
or how loyal they were to the boss, but rather by how much they were able
to grow their local economy. On top of that,
a large part of local government revenue was to be generated through land sales. And given that the value of land appreciates
when the right infrastructure is built. If local governors wanted to further
their career in the party, one of their best options
was to build infrastructure such that they could get more revenue and increase
the GDP of their province or city. And okay, maybe also skim
a little bit off the top in the process. Importantly, these incentives
meant that local Chinese governors were really keen to make things
as easy as possible for foreigners that wanted to invest in their city. For example,
as Professor Rajan describes in this book, when an Indian businessman wanted
to invest in a middle sized city in China, he was met at the airport by the deputy
major, taken to visit a possible site on the same day, and then immediately
taken to the Major's office, where all the necessary paperwork
had already been filled out and any problems he raised could be dealt
with by the local government. Similarly, when Elon Musk came to China,
he was able to have his Shanghai factory up and running in record time
because the local Shanghai government officials
cleared all legal obstacles for him. Contrast this to India, where
while the central government assured citizens that it was now
a great destination for FDI, its local government often actively
frustrated the arrival of foreign firms by strictly upholding India's
difficult regulations and making it time
consuming to get around them. In summary,
following the insights from Professor Rajan, China was able to outgrow India initially because it had a better level
of education. And while both countries liberalized
their economies, only China was able to successfully invest on a colossal scale
and attract enough foreign direct investment
to supercharge its economic growth. Finally, it's not that India's
central government was not aware that it needed
to invest more and attract FDI. No, the deeper reason
why India was not able to keep up with China is that its local governments
did not play along. Whereas in China,
local governors had the right incentives to promote both local investment and FDI. And sadly, if we next turn
to the work of Professor Davesh Kapur, I'm afraid it will become clear
that not only did dysfunctional local governments hold India
back in the past, they also mean that even today, India can never grow
like China. Okay. To understand
why India's local governments are failing to unleash a China style miracle,
let's now turn to Professor Kapoor, who has identified
the three most plausible explanations. The first explanation
is really straightforward. India's local governments are terribly understaffed,
especially when compared to China, which greatly increased its local
government capacity during its growth. Miracle. Indeed, if we look at this graph,
we can see that the structure of India's government
employee count is basically the opposite of that of China
and the United States. Whereas in the US and China,
by far most government employees work at the local level and only
some at the state or federal level. In India it is the other way around. Most of India's government employees
work at the state and to a lesser extent, federal level,
whereas only a few work at local level. This can explain why India's
local governments were not able to invest or help foreign investors around the rules on the same scale
as their Chinese counterparts did. But if just local capacity was the only
problem, then it could simply be solved by giving the local governments
more money to hire more people, right? Well, sadly, that will likely
not completely fix the problem. You see,
there is something really strange going on with India's local governments
despite high unemployment. Many local governments
have thousands of unfilled open positions. Even worse,
some of India's poorest local governments do not even spend all the money
that they get from the central government. So what else is going on? Well, this brings us to Kapur's
second explanation of why in this, local governments
are not living up to their potential. India's infamous caste system,
which divides people into a hierarchy of social categories
based on their birth. But before getting into how we should note that the caste system
has effectively been outlawed. However,
despite that, in many parts of the country it is still very much a political reality. The caste system can explain India's dysfunctional local governments
in three different ways. Firstly, realizing that the caste system
was still strong at the local government level, India's founders on purpose
made sure that local governments were not too powerful which can explain
why this graph looks the way that it does. Secondly, even if a local government
has adequate capacity, they might not have the right incentives,
meaning that they may frustrate the implementation
of well-meant central government policies because it is not in line
with a caste system. As an example, Professor Kapoor mentions
that quite a few federal education programs where schools were built
to improve the education of girls failed at the local level
because and I'm quoting, what happens within
the classroom is affected by caste and gender norms. Thirdly, in some extreme cases,
the caste system, even leads to government vacancies
potentially being left open because they only have candidates
from higher costs. For example, in their book The Narrow Order, Professor Acemoglu and Robinson describe
how in one of India's poorer states Bihar, the state had thousands of vacancies
for engineers that were not filled despite high unemployment. Why not? Well, because those qualified to be
engineers are typically from higher costs. But because the province's reigning
governor, Lalu Prasad Yadav, was from a lower caste,
he refused to fill these positions. Of course, as a consequence, everyone suffered because the government of the here
was so severely understaffed that it could not even spend all the money
it got allocated from the central government
to upgrade the local infrastructure. But okay, that is an extreme case
which may not be applicable to all states, but it is applicable to
all of any of though is the third reason why its local governments
are not enabling businesses like their Chinese counterparts,
and that is that India is a democracy. Now, I want to stress that in itself,
this is not a problem at all. Sure, in China,
the incentives of a promotion in the party meant that local governments
could override local concerns to build infrastructure and go out
of their way to attract foreign firms. However, in well-functioning democracies,
this does not need to be a problem, since there the democratic process itself
could give local governors the incentive to invest in their cities
and to attract foreign firms. After all, if you as a local governor
grow your economy, you know, then you're more likely
to be reelected as local governor again. Indeed, democracy has produced the vast
majority of growth miracles, ranging from West Germany to Italy to Japan
and to the United States. However, unlike these countries, Professor
Kapur claims that India is a so-called precocious democracy,
meaning that a country became democratic before it was
perhaps ready to become democratic again. Professor Kapur discusses three reasons why this is holding
India's local governments back. The first is that a precocious
democracy can get into a vicious cycle in which it delivers poor public services
like schools and health care at a time. But it is established as a consequence. Wealthier
people will exit the public system and start using private schools
and hospitals instead. And therefore they are now less
willing to pay taxes, making local government services
even more dysfunctional. Indeed, as Professor Kapur notes,
local governments in India in particular seem to be very hesitant
to raise their taxes, the taxes
that they need to improve their cities. But sadly, there's more. The second reason why being a precocious
democracy is holding India back is that because India's
so divided local government officials that were elected by their specific caste
or religious group or, you know, any other interest group
tend to prefer rewarding their voters by giving them subsidies
or other specific benefits, rather than to invest in public services
that can be enjoyed by all. Finally, in precocious democracies,
politicians will tend to emphasize public goods that are highly visible
and relatively easy to provide. For example, they may prefer to invest
in hyper modern metros rather than to invest
in improving the education system, of which the results
will only be seen after a few years. Of course, this, you know,
happens in any democracy, but more so in precocious democracies
is is what Professor Kapoor argues. So on the surface, India did not grow as fast as China
because it lacked basic education. They didn't invest as much and didn't
attract as much FDI. But the deeper reason
is that India's local government did not have the capacity,
nor the right incentives to improve education, invest a lot and to attract FDI due to a lack of personnel
and wrong incentives provided by the caste system and India
being a precocious democracy necessarily. Despite a lot of good intentions
by the Modi government, all of these causes of India's local
government dysfunction are still in place and this is why I am confident to say
that India can never grow like China, especially now that Modi,
who became increasingly autocratic in recent years,
lost his majority in parliament. So does that mean that there is no hope
for India to ever catch up to China? No. I'm actually quite optimistic because there are still a few reasons
to be optimistic about India's economy. First of all, if we compare
India to the place it was in the 1980s, we will see that well may not have gone
through miracle growth. People are now better educated
and its infrastructure has received a major upgrade, especially on the digital
and financial side. And given that foreign companies
are increasingly looking for an alternative
to China, India is, in theory, really well positioned to attract
a lot of foreign direct investment. Now, of course, FDI in India has not yet
been anything to write home about due to the fact that the local governments
do not have the capacity or incentives to help foreign firms
navigate its complicated rules. However, now that India has elected
a more democratic coalition government, some have argued that this could mean
that Modi now has to work more closely together with local governments
to push through reforms. Closer cooperation in a divided nation
will never put in there on the path of China, but it could put it
on the path to the United States. A big, divided nation
that went through a slow, messy. But what, in the end turned out to be the most successful
growth miracle of all time. Finally, perhaps more importantly,
as Professor Kapur notes, a successful implementation
of various programs such as opening bank accounts, gas connections, and toilets
that connect to the sewage system. This demonstrates that slowly but surely, local government
capabilities are improving. But yeah, I don't expect a China style
miracle anytime soon, but I am still optimistic about India's
potential to grow in the upcoming decades. But yeah, that is my take. Do you agree with me
that India can never grow like China, but that it is now actually
well positioned for its own unique, messy, slower, but perhaps ultimately more
successful growth miracle? Let me know in the comments below. Finally, given that primary education
is often a local government responsibility and that this capacity
has recently increased, this could mean that this is
where improvement will be felt and next, which could be huge,
because having a broadly shared basic level of education
will give more Indians access to an unprecedented wealth of online
materials, such as the unique lessons
provided by today's video sponsor. Brilliant. Brilliant’s thousands of lessons in
math, data analysis, programing and A.I. are unique because I focus on learning
by doing rather than learning through reading a book
or by watching a video lecture. Each of their lessons,
crafted by high profile educators from the likes of MIT, Caltech,
Google, and more, is filled with hands on interactive exercises,
which is a method that has been proven to be six times more effective
than watching lecture videos. So instead of just memorizing knowledge,
Brilliant helps build your critical thinking
skills through problem solving. Problem solving that brilliant encourages
you to do a little bit of every day by providing fun, short lessons that
you can do whenever you have the time. Take Brilliant's
growing number of programing courses where through the type of learning. By doing that you see here,
you will be able to get a core understanding of key programing elements
like loops and conditionals in no time. You can even get started by building programs
from day one in Python with their drag and drop editor, an essential skill
that still saves me hours every week. As I almost always use Python to collect and clean
the data that I use for my visuals. So if you want to develop deep knowledge
in a fun and accessible way, visit brilliant.org/moneymacro
or click on the link in the description below to get a free 30 day trial
and a 20% discount on their annual premium subscription.