Chicago's Best Ideas: Are Property Rights Really So Good?

Video Statistics and Information

Video
Captions Word Cloud
Reddit Comments
Captions
- Welcome to our first episode of Chicago's Best Ideas. And let's see. How about we just begin with some administrative stuff like, what will happen? Where's your food? And all that kind of thing. So because we're in this room-- like there's lunch provided. You can get it after the talk. And then you can bring it to your next class. You can get everybody else around you envious. So that's number one. And then I thought I would just say something about the history of the CBI series because it's kind of fun to know because you're a law student. You should know history. And then we can get into the talk, and I'll try to make it relatively short because 1 out of 10 people needs to ask the question afterwards, so they will learn more from questions. And so here we go. So first of all, the idea of CBI, as we call them, was started at the Law School's 100th anniversary. And the idea of each talk is the faculty member tries to talk about some idea that came out of this Law School that was like a great idea or an interesting idea or a well-supported idea or something. So for example, the talk could have been like what's the Coase theorem and then a little explanation of it followed by what's its effect in the modern world, or what does the speaker think the good and bad about it or some modernizing of the ideas. So it's not like aren't we great? Aren't we great? Well, we are great. But aren't we great? But then it can be like-- let me tell you what I think of it today. So that's what we're going to do. And my talk really is centered on what I think is really three of Chicago's Best Ideas rolled into one. But the opening move is about a well-known book by our colleague, Prof. Richard Epstein. And his idea was called Simple Rules for a Complex World. So I'm going to explain his idea first and then give you a couple applications of it, some that are in his well-known book translated into like 15 languages actually. And then talk a little bit about it. We'll puzzle about some solutions to it. And then again, it will be your turn to question, and I'll try to answer them. If I don't get to your question, you can always email me. And I'm happy to talk to you about it afterwards. So you have to run off to your next class. And then we'll figure that out. So here's Professor Epstein's idea. Again, Simple Rules for a Complex World. It's something like if you're normal before you come to law school, like a naive citizen, an intelligent naive citizen, we think that complexity is really good. Every time you see a simple rule, you think, it should be a little complicated. You drive on Lakeshore Drive, and the speed limit is 45 miles an hour. And then everybody says, that's ridiculous. That's a simple rule. Just one speed limit. That's no good. It should be a different rule on rainy weather, good weather, how crowded the road is, day, night. That would be a complex rule, like 15 different speed limits. That would be a better world. Most people think before they come to law school, life should be complex. Oh, you have tax deduction. Let's do this, and we give to that charity. This and that charity. It should be complicated. And Epstein's insight or claim is-- no, no, you can come down. It's fine. Raise your hand if you want somebody to sit next to you because you need new friends. [LAUGHTER] OK. Come on down, really. So Epstein's idea is no, actually simple rules are really pretty good, and there are a lot of reasons he likes simple rules. And again, I'll give examples. But his main idea which I'll come back to at the end is that the more complex-- first of all, it's easier to understand the rule is simple. That's kind of obvious. But also, the more complex the rule, the easier it is for people to bribe the government or get their way around the rule. Or interest groups will get involved. They'll change some of the rule and all that. And really, going to be in the business of trying to-- Epstein would say government should be in as little business as possible. But when it does get involved, you should have simple rules that's much harder to manipulate. And the book shows this in area after area after area of law. So I'll give you an example, a pro simple rule example. I mean, he's mostly interested in property rights. But let's do a different rule. Say for example, you have a patent. You want people to invent things, and have a productive society and all that. So at first, again, if you're a normal citizen, you would think as many people do today when you take patent law you'll see this. Many people think, oh, we really need a complex rule. We have this very simple rule in government, a pretty simple rule. If you invent something that reaches a certain category, then you get a patent period of certain length. Oh, how could that be right? It should be the patent period is longer for some kinds of goods, shorter for other goods, maybe for-- you have some cure for COVID. It should have a patent period of a certain length to empower the production of information over there. But maybe it's something less complicated or more complicated should have a different patent period. And there are many proposals out there for very different patent systems, depending on the group. So someone should study [INAUDIBLE] and figure out the optimal patent period. And you see the problem with patent law. On the one hand, the longer the patent, the more people are encouraged to invent things. On the other hand, the longer the patent, the more this is monopoly power that the patent holder has. And law should be trying to figure out the divide. How could it be that the same divide is true in all these industries. So we should figure that out. That's basically most people's reaction. Epstein's insight, well-known insight, was to say, well, not so fast. Because the more you have different patent period for different industries, the more people in industries will lobby the government and maybe even bribe the government. Let's say interest groups will form, and they'll go like, me, me, me. Oh, my industry. We really need a longer patent system. Look at this example. Look at that example. It should be longer and shorter. Over there, it should be shorter or marginally longer. And Epstein's thing is, hey, that's a waste of time and effort, what we call here a transactions class. And B, maybe not such a good idea in the first place because there's no reason to think that the government will get the rule right. The government will be so influenced by these interest groups that it will probably end up with the wrong patent period. I have a feeling in the back of his mind is the more complex the rule, the more government will get involved. He's pretty libertarian. He would like less government involvement. So if you have to have a simple rule, maybe you'll get a little bit less government involvement in the first place. That's basically the simple rules I'll give. Let me give one other example so you get the hang of it. And besides, I've tried to say a few funny things there, and no one's laughed at any of my jokes. So I'm kind of a little insulted. So I'll try another one. We'll see if it's funnier. So every five minutes, I'm going to pause and tell people in the back to come on down. It's ridiculous to stand in the back. Come on down. OK. So here's another example. Take taxes. Our income tax system is really very complicated. It's not just an income tax. Probably an income tax, the sales tax, the property tax, this tax, that tax, and it's complex. You follow your form, or your company that files its form. The deductions for this and exclusions for that. It's really a very complicated tax system. And it gets more and more complicated over time as people either lobby or legislative groups figure out oh, well, we can manipulate this, manipulate that. And maybe there should be a foreign tax credit, and we should do this and that. And the code gets longer and longer and longer. And Epstein, I think, correctly says, well, on the one hand, a complex rule might make sense if you had a brilliant government it might structure the income tax to get really very, very clever work effort on behalf of people and invention effort, information effort. It could be complicated and very sophisticated and good. But in reality, it leads to a lot of bargaining with the state or lobbying with the state. And the system becomes very corrupt. Oh, I want my kind of entity would be tax exempt. I want my kind of entity to have a $500,000 exclusion. And the system gets so complicated that when you look at-- anyone who's taken tax law knows this-- and everyone should take tax law. It just looks like wow, line after line after line in the internal revenue code just seems like interest group influence. It's like so political. We'd be better off if we just had a simple system. Of course, the system is not so simple to get rid of all that because people could still lobby about the rate of tax. People will then want a lower tax rate or higher tax rate. Maybe that's too complicated. What's income? What's not income? In fact, Epstein likes a flat tax. You know what flat tax is? Every time there's a new election, somebody says, I want flat tax. Let's just have a flat tax of 18% of all the income you have. And Epstein says, well, that might be pretty good. Maybe people would stop lobbying so much for different taxes. They would still argue about what the rate should be, but that might be simpler. So he likes the flat tax [INAUDIBLE] Notice you might say, well, why stop there? Why not an even simpler tax like maybe the sales tax, sales tax on everything? But then people would say, correct me. Well, that's pretty regressive. Poor people need to eat about the same number of food as Bill Gates. Maybe a little bit less is what they're able to eat. But Bill Gates is not a big consumer of food, doesn't like fancy restaurants. It would seem a little odd to live in a world where Bill Gates paid as much tax as the average law professor, like a well-known really underprivileged, low paying, down group. Thank you for laughing. [LAUGHTER] So OK, he's not crazy, Epstein. Well-- [LAUGHTER] He's not totally crazy. And he said-- and he essentially says without saying so, well, a flat sales tax to raise all the government money, that may not be such a good idea. And income tax is probably a good idea, but a flat tax would be a little lower. Anyway, I think you see the idea that its simplicity versus complexity. How do we know which is better? Epstein's famous idea is simplicity is much better probably because it eliminates a lot of interest group influences, eliminates a lot of complexity of even knowing how do you live your life, knowing what the income tax is really like. If it was just a simple rule, a much better idea about when to go to work, when to retire, when to build a factory. It would really be much simpler, and he likes all that. Now before I go to problems that raise [INAUDIBLE],, notice a couple of Chicago Best Ideas that are really related to this. So our most famous of Chicago Best Idea is surely the Coase theorem, a Nobel Prize winning effort, developed in this very building. It's kind of exciting. And it's also, when you think about it, a pretty simple rule because the whole idea of the Coase theorem is something like the government throws a rule out there, throws the property right out there-- and it doesn't really matter whether it's the right property right. Like who should get the property right. And the optimistic version of the Coase theorem. It doesn't really matter because people will bargain around the rule. If they give me the rule that I'm entitled to all your income in the future, I own you because you're a law student and I educate you. You will essentially pay me-- no, no, we're not coming to Law School like let's come up with a deal where-- this is an exaggerated rule. Let's come up with a rule where I will have some incentive to go to work, so I'll give you law school tuition. And then while they work I get to keep all that money. If I assign-- if the governor or somebody or even the King of England has signed everybody, all the land of the Uni--or what came to be the United States, people would come. They wouldn't want to do anything with the land, and they would eventually say to the King, I could really mow the grass over here. I can grow crops over here, if I have the rights to the land. And they would pay to buy land, and then property rights would be allocated accordingly. This is like the most optimistic version of the Coase theorem, it's a very libertarian idea, like if you can count on people to have some idea of what the future would look like. And if you can count on people to bargain with one another and speak the same language and all that stuff that you've learned in your 1L year, then OK the rule really doesn't matter. Notice how simple the rule is. Just assign the property right wherever it is. People will bargain within the rule, and the world will be a better place. That's again, very Epstein-like though the Coase theorem was before Epstein. Another CBI idea was developed by-- in corporate law, just to show you that this is all over the place, whereby Easterbrook and Fischel. And their idea was there's a big problem in corporate law. Being a legal problem of corporate law. What about ideas that you develop within the corporation? You work for the corporation and you, while working for the corporation, have a good idea. You discover oil, and then you want to leave the company and start an oil company on your own or go to another company. Should you have the rights to that idea, or should the corporation be able to say, we basically own you. While you were working for us 9:00 to 5:00, you had this idea of where to look for oil. So you have stolen a corporate opportunity by going somewhere else. Again, very much like the the Coase theorem, like Epstein. Easterbrook and Fischel say, look, this is a very complicated area of law. The governing rule should be the corporation owns everything. And then in order to get you to work for them, they will sometimes say, oh, if you develop an idea here, it's yours. Or they will sometimes say, you can leave. It'll make us look good. Other employees will want to come here, so we'll let you have it. Think about your own life. You go work for the government or a nonprofit or for a law firm. And you write a novel at night. You can imagine a world in which the law firm said to you, we got you 24/7. We can send you assignments all the time. Your writing that novel, really stole time from us. We own the novel. It's a corporate opportunity that belongs to the corporation, meaning the law firm, not really a corporation. And then they don't do that. They basically say, if you wrote a novel at night, it's all yours. And why did they do that? Because it makes them a better employer and people want to go work for that law firm. They know that if you did not own a novel, you'd never write a novel at night. And there are great novelists in [INAUDIBLE] law firms. [INAUDIBLE] So again, that's the Easterbrook/Fischel idea, it's really the same thing. Let's have a very simple rule. The corporation owns all the property. But actually, people will bargain around the rule or the corporation will voluntarily change the rule because it wants you to go work for them and wants you to be more productive. OK, I think you get the idea. There are three Chicago famous ideas, and they're all about a very simple rule about ownership and then equal bargaining around the rule. Lots and lots of law is like this. Many, many areas of law are basically simple, unique allocations of rules. I made a list of them, which probably won't interest you but only interest me. But property law, very simple rule. Contract law, very simple rule. One person wins and one person doesn't. It just goes on and on like that. Patent law, I already said. There are other areas of law that are not like that. Tort law often likes a division of the rule, comparative negligence sort of thing Family law likes the division of the rule between members of couples. So there are some areas of law that are binary you might say and some areas of law that are simple. One person owns. That is a major theme in law and something that the Chicago basic idea or famous idea [INAUDIBLE].. Now let me tell you a puzzle I have. Or one more example just because it will come out later. The government's rules start out very simple. For example, the government used to run the post office. I'm sorry. Most people here are pretty young, and you probably don't know what a post office is. There used to be this thing called mail, and they would deliver the mail to your house like twice a day in the beginning. Underground and some places like Manhattan, above ground and other places, very, very efficient. And then it started getting inefficient. And so FedEx and other companies grow up and-- compare them for a minute. For many, many years, the post office says, the governmental entity really follow the simple rule principle. It was one price for a letter, basically. And they didn't do boxes in the beginning. They didn't do anything like that. They did mail of a certain type. And there was one price. FedEx came along, and they said, no, no, we're going to have many, many different prices, depending on what it weighs, how big the package it fits in, how fast you want it. If you want one day delivery, it will be more expensive, two days. Forever will be no date delivery. So FedEx pricing system was really a complex rule. The government's rule was really very simple. Well, most of us now-- so in a way, it conforms Epstein. Epstein said great, simple rule government, very, very good. But most of us now would say, I don't know. FedEx is probably better than the post office. With FedEx by using varied rules seem to do a better job. It made money unlike the post office, which costs you a fortune in taxes in addition to mailing a letter. And the FedEx is much more reliable and actually shows up on time. And the government with all its advantages-- free post boxes anywhere they want and all that. It's really very inefficient. So why is that? It seems like the government's simple rule which follows the Chicago Best idea doesn't seem to work so well. And the FedEx seems to work really well, and it has complex pricing mechanism. Of course, the post office is now probably FedEx a little bit. Its pricing system has gotten a little bit more complex. This is all over the place. The government chose who could be a taxi driver and who can't. Having a taxi license [INAUDIBLE].. For many years, taxis were like a fixed price system. The government controlled, a very simple rule. You think Epstein would like it? Well, no. Along came Uber. And Uber's doing pretty complex system. Depends on time of the day, depends on the demand, depends on how many cars are out there. It's real complexity. But we look on our phones, and we can see the complexity divided and how much it cost. So complexity seems to work very well over there. This is a general theme that I now want to question. And the question is something like-- a lot of times when you look at what the government does, a good way to judge the government, I think, is to try to compare the government to the private market. It's a good check on government. Try to see where the private market does a better job or worse job. And then if I'm running a piece of the government, I always like to think, well, how is the private market doing? Maybe I should be a little bit like the private market if the private market delivers the service really well. That's what happens in the post office, right? Post office, you probably imitate what FedEx does. I have to give a little anecdote while I'm there, which I haven't told in a while and I can't help it, so. As you know, President Obama taught at this Law School. And one time-- so he was, as they say in China, an employee of mine when I was dean of the Law School. OK. So one time, we were having lunch, and he was not yet president. That was not funny. He was not yet president, but it was clear that he was going to be the president. And we had lunch together. And he was like feeling me out for like members of the faculty that I thought would be good at or would like government [INAUDIBLE]. And then we go through a few members of the faculty and I say, no, no, no, because I wanted them to stay here. [LAUGHTER] And then occasionally I'd go, oh that person would be great at this. And he said, oh, well, what about you? Is there a job you really like? I'm not promising anything, but is there a job you really like? And he probably thought I was going to say something like, be a judge Yeah, I really love my job. I'm not leaving it for one of those jobs. And I said, well, actually, I've had this lifelong desire to run the post office. [LAUGHTER] I'm not kidding, because it seems so inefficient. And I think there are a lot of things-- he's like, really, like what? I said, well, for starters, we should have three time a week delivery instead of six time a week delivery. And then have half as many people running the post office. And I gave a couple ideas I have for post office. Then he just looks at me like I am a total idiot. And he says, so you think if I am the president I could have changed the post office by appointing you to run the post office? And he just looked at me and said, you have no idea how the country works. I would never have enough power to change the post office. It's a-- dream on. It cannot be changed. You need to do like a really unimportant job like Secretary of State or something like that. The post office, no, no no, no. Really chasing me a little bit. What presidents can you [INAUDIBLE]?? Oh, anyway, so I like this idea of the government should be looking at the private sector, and the private sector does something very different from the government. If it seems to be working well, then maybe the government should imitate the private sector. We should think about how the private sector does. So for example-- hospitals are the most famous example of this. About half of our health care, serious health care, is delivered by government-owned hospitals, usually state or city. And half of it is run by private enterprise. And it's interesting to compare them. And if you're running the state-owned hospital, you would want to look at how the private hospitals work. So for example, a real problem with hospitals is that you have to wait a long time to see a doctor because people don't show up for their appointments. If you're running a government hospital, you probably want to look well, how does the private market control as we try to make sure that people keep their appointments? And then you might want to copy it in the public sector. There may be pricing, how do you deal with insurance companies. You probably learn a lot by copying just like the post office is copying FedEx. It might be-- even taxis have begun copying Uber. It might be that you should do this with many, many things. So when you apply it to today's topic, wait a minute, this is very complicated. Epstein says we should have simple rules in the public sector. And we've seen some simple rules that seem to work pretty well. When you look at the private sector, it's full of complexity. When I think about airline seats, it's very complicated and beautiful. They change the price depending on how people have reserved seats. They change the price for complexity for where it's landing. Then different private market pay more for getting a good seat, a bad seat. It's really a complex pricing system, and it seems to work very well, even better than Uber, so to speak. Well, wait a minute-- I can give you a lot of examples like that but I think you get the idea. The private market seems now to really love complexity. So why should public market also like complexity. We like the fact when we compare-- I think most of us think it's very clever when the private market varies complexity, varies prices a lot, and other attributes. You go rent an apartment-- it seems sort of crazy if you went to rent an apartment and they said, well, apartments here are $1,000 a month And you said, well, I really want a two bedroom apartment. They said, $1,000 a month-- apartment. Oh, I really want the 10th floor. $1,000 a month-- apartment. You would think that a simple rule was a crazy thing. Of course, it's a complex rule, depending on what size of apartment you have and the floor it's on, how much has been renovated, and all that kind of thing, how long your lease is for. So it goes on and on. The private market is very complex. So why is the government so simple? They draft somebody. Everybody gets the same price. They do the equivalent of renting something out. Everybody gets the same price. Now the private market is not always simple. I think in the military, in some sense, it's very, very simple. If you are a private, you get a certain amount of money. That's simple compared to private market. But on the other hand, of how you get promoted is very, very complex. How they buy airplanes is very, very complex. It's not more complex than the private market, but they're both pretty complex over there. Large parts of the government pricing are very, very simple. And yet the private market-- I might have said this backwards. The public market there seems very simple if you follow Epstein's advice, the CBI advice. But there the private market seems to thrive on complexity. So maybe the government should be imitating the private market. So that's a sense of a puzzle that I want to solve before I finish and grade for questions. The question is, well, why is the private market so often complex in a way that seems very productive. Meanwhile, there's this argument by Epstein and others that the public should really be very simple. There's a real advantage to simple rules. And there's a real-- on the other hand, the private market has complexity. If it's really valuable for the government, which I'll call the public market-- if it's really valuable for the government to learn something from private enterprise, then maybe this argument should be that the government should be much more complex because the private market is really incredibly complex. The only part of the private market that's not complex is nonprofits. Everybody pays the same amount of money to take a course, for example, on the margin. We don't say, a course is crowded, now the price is rising for the course. But the private market would mostly do it-- we're a nonprofit, so we don't do that. We try to make you feel like everybody's equal and oh, you know, all that kind of thing. Of course, we are complex with your different scholarships. Colleges do that even more. It's really quite complicated. We're not allowed to bid for student athletes. Well, of course, companies do bid for private athletes and so forth. So the private market sometimes hides this complexity. But the basic idea and I think everybody is clear like if it's true that the government should be simple, why is that-- why doesn't the government want to learn from the private market, which tends to be increasing complex all the time as it figures out pricing and doesn't charge the same amount to every piece of food in the supermarket and all that sort of thing? So I think there are three kinds of answers. You're going to have your own but I'm going to offer three kinds of answers to that, and maybe the third is something we'll learn from. The first one is maybe the most obv-- they get a little bit more complicated as we go along. The first one is something like, I'll call agency costs to sound like a Chicago law professor, which is the private market has a lot of advantages over the government. For starters, if you're an employer in the private market, you can fire people, right? It's really easy. If they don't do a good job, you fire them. And you can char-- you can give them commissions. Oh, if you sell more cars, we'll give you a commission, pay you more if you sell more cars. Private market is yeah, it's complex, but that's because the manager of the firm has a lot of possibilities, a lot of variation and it has freedom to do things. I think the hiring and firing is really the main one. If you don't do a good job, you're fired, at least in the United States. The countries that don't allow that, not doing so well actually. So the private market seems to really thrive on this kind of openness of the entrepreneur to hire, fire, give raises over there, promotions over there, et cetera. The public market cannot do that for good reasons. Probably it's afraid of favoritism. So once you're in the public service, everybody at that grade gets the same pay. It's very, very hard to fire a public employee, almost impossible. As you know, for schoolteachers, if they're really, really terrible, they just move them to some room and have them sit there all day. Firing them is just almost impossible. So they don't get paid more for being a good teacher. In the private market, of course, they would get paid more for being a good teacher. So the public market is simple. You'd think Epstein would like it. A private market is complex, and I think we understand why. There are these big agency costs, and the private market solves them by being flexible in a way that, for probably good reasons, we don't let the public market do it. It's not a profit-maximizing firm, so it doesn't have this flexibility. Instead, there's not a lot of playing favorites in a lot of kind of ways. OK. Another way to say this is we might say, we bind the government to simple rules. We not only have simple rules, but they're bound to have simple rules. We don't let for the public market, that is the government, be as flexible as possible. I'll just call that dismissing employee solution, which I think is really a big deal. The second one, maybe a little less obvious, which is the private market has this real advantage. They don't think so, but we consumers think so. They have this real advantage of repeat play. If you're a building contractor in the private market, you do a good job because you want people to tell their friends to hire you. If the building goes up and it goes up on time. And then other people hire you. Whereas the public market doesn't really have that. It's a solo buyer. And it's really-- and seller. And it's really hard for it to have a repeat play. If you think the military does a bad job, it gets too much money and doesn't do a very good job, you can't say, all right, you're fired. New military, come on in. It doesn't work very well. Sometimes you can do it. You can have public schools competing with private schools, for example. But usually, it's very, very hard for a public market to have real repeat play. And by not having a repeat play, it really needs to be governed by very different rules, whereas the private market, we let it fool around with hiring or firing or pricing or this, that. Doesn't do good job? Well, I'm just going to move on somewhere else. And then they are controlled by this repeat play opportunity. So that's a big difference between private and public. The third explanation, I think, for this private and public distinction is, I think, the most important and goes back to the Chicago Best Idea that I started with, which is more or less, you have to worry about interest groups. So in a complex world, think of a tax code. If it's complex, you get a deduction for this, bigger deduction for that, 20% off over there, exclusions over there. Interest groups do play a very, very important role. They can come in and say, well, your code is already 500 pages long. Why don't you just change this rule over there to this kind of use of property? Or why don't you change that rule over there? I mean, if you're Chicago and you pay property tax on your building, there's enormous play of grant seeking. Grant seeking, meaning you form an interest group and you go there. And then the government wants you to have an interest group, so you bribe them or take them out for free lunches or contribute to their campaigns. It's just back and forth between the government and private enterprise of oh, we have this thing to give you. We can give you monopoly power. Give us something in return. And then I'll give you a license to this, a license to that. And it's just playing back and forth between the government and the private sector. This does not occur in the private market. I mean, what can an interest group do? It can go to Whole Foods, and it can say, we'll take you out to free lunch if you sell my favorite kind of peanuts. And Whole Foods would say, what are you, like crazy? First of all, I have peanuts that aren't selling very well. I'm going to get fired. I'm motivated by the market and by my boss and so forth, whereas the government is not motivated that way. So the government has all these "bennies" to give out, mostly kinds of monopoly in power. You can't just start a new hospital. You can't just start a new school even in the public market. You certainly can't start your own military in the public market. You can't even start your own police force next to the public market. So you're really beholden. And now the question is, where do interest groups do best? Meaning from our point of view, where they do more harm. Do they do more harm in the simple world, or they do more harm in a complex world? This is actually a complicated question. In a simple world, every time the interest gets its way, it's huge. Imagine that the whole world is governed by a flat tax of 18%. And now you get some interest group that comes and says, I was kind of thinking maybe that's more if you lower the flat tax to 16%. Well, if the government could do that or would do that in return for donations to campaigns or whatever, that would be like billions and billions of dollars gaining to all these companies or maybe to all of you as your graduated from the Law School. But everybody watches that more carefully. It's a little hard to see that. And besides then, there'd be other interest groups that want more government spending that would battle it. No, no, no, we need more taxes so you can buy more goods and all that. So really, I think-- if you think about it, interest groups do much, much better in a complex world. The more rules there are, the more room there is for an interest group to go like, oh, just one. Just little small advantage over there that maybe you should use this kind of wood when you're building that little platform over there to get handicap access. We have such a rule in Illinois. You don't even notice this kind of rule over there. And the interest group does very well. If there are a thousand government rules, interest groups can come and manipulate four at a time, one at a time. They can get their way without anyone noticing. So I think that's a really pretty good explanation of why the government is probably better off having simple rules. It's much harder for interest groups to come in and do their thing at our public expense, whereas the private market probably doesn't suffer that problem, he does a good job. And the interest group, in the private market if there are 15 kinds of gasoline sold and 4,000 kinds of coffee sold, that works pretty well in the private market. It's not like interest groups come and say, I'll bribe you to sell more vanilla coffee. No, the market will take care of that, and there isn't room for extraction like interest groups, whereas the government were to supply our coffee like whoa. You'd have interest groups crawling all over the place to make money and deny us Plein Air. Oh, goodness. You can only imagine the government running that, it would really be awful. So I think that does get back to Epstein's thing about the advantage of simple rules, and maybe he is actually on to something. I want to conclude by just saying, I think in your generation, speaking out to law students-- I think in your generation, probably the government will get more complex rather than more simple. And that's because information is easier to acquire. The government, just like Whole Foods can monitor everything we buy and figure out what price to charge and what products to have. The government can do that also. Information is cheaper than it used to be. And so the government can watch a little bit more carefully like what roads we go on, who's going to buy electric cars, what's going to happen. And probably the government will also become more like Uber, if you will, and monitor our information and then maybe have more efficient rule. And there might be much better rules just the way the private market has more complexity. So it might well be that, in the end, the government will become more like the private market with more complexity, but we'll also be able to monitor the governmet a little bit better because we will also have information about what the government does. So I'm actually pretty optimistic about this. Maybe that's wrong. So I promised that half the time will be yours for questions and answers. I was going to bring little presents to throw people who ask good questions. But I'm not going to do that. I'm going to count on you to ask good questions. And more hands up. the shorter answers will be-- and so forth. So why don't you be aggressive and ask questions. Please. - Yeah, so-- - And I'll repeat every question, both for the recording and because-- I'm sure your question will be clear-- but I can mangle it and-- - I mean, we'll see about that. I don't know. But I don't know too much about this, but I assume in administrative or regulatory rulemaking, there is less special interest power. That could be wrong, but that's just an assumption. So insofar as that is true, is that one solution to this problem, right? Because sometimes I mean, it does seem like complex rules are better that are able to achieve whatever the goal of this rule is. So is divesting power and giving it to some regulatory body a solution to this problem? - So let me repeat the question with a little-- [LAUGHTER] --twist, negative twist. It goes something like, well, the problem is democracy. [LAUGHTER] Like there are always politicians over there, and they want money, and they have ways of giving out stuff. And so therefore, complex rules make them more powerful. So isn't the solution to have an administrative state-- let's have the environment controlled by an agency, and they'll be like lifetime employees. And then as long as we can get talented people into the agency, they can come up with more complex rules about what we ought to be able to dump into the river and whatnot and at what price. And their rules might get more complex. It might be less subject to an interest group pressure because the agency is just there. And only in an oblique way does it need interest groups to like it better. Is that sort of-- is that a fair question? Well, call me old-fashioned, but I thought that we did things like became an independent country and fought World War II in order to be a democracy. So I thought we were supposed to like democracy. I know that, for reasons I don't get, that's not very popular in this building. In this building, most professors seem to love the administrative state. Like oh, agency this, agency that. They can solve-- any problem you name, an agency can solve the problem. They have experts. They'll do cost-benefit analysis. They'll do this. They'll do that. That's just not my experience with agencies. I don't know about yours. When will they give up? The environment does not seem to be in very good shape to me, and it's been controlled by agencies for a long period of time. So I think that the problem-- so now I'm going to be political. I think the problem with believing all the good things about agencies is to say, well-- it's a little bit like universities. It's impossible to ever show anyone that the agency's not a good solution. Because whenever you say, oh, the agencies are not doing very well. Look at the environment. Or, the agency's not doing very well, look at the public schools. A majority of people, meaning law students, would say, oh, that's because they're underfunded. You've just got to give them more money. And then they can have more employees and more experts then they'll do a better job. And then people on the other side will just say-- whether they're liberal or conservative, will just say, well, how will we ever do a test to know whether agencies are the right solution? Whenever I say they're not doing a good job, you say, well, that's because they're unfunded. I've never heard anyone say an agency is overfunded. So this worries me a little bit. So I don't know how to judge whether agencies are better or worse than democratically elected people. So I understand what you're saying. That maybe the more we have agencies, the more complex the society will be. And when you vote for the president, it's very hard to change your vote based on whether agencies grew or shrunk or whatever it is. It's very difficult. So yeah, that's a-- it's a different kind of topic. It's like, do you generally have faith in administrative agencies or not? I have a feeling the answer is in between. I have a feeling that in some industries, if you will, some areas, we think an agency probably works pretty well. And in other agencies-- in other areas, we probably think agencies don't work very well. So the ultimate question is not simple rules-- this was going to be my conclusion. The ultimate question is not simple rules versus complex rules but rather what should we allocate to the public sector and what should we allocate to the private sector. And I'll give you that the public sector mostly includes agencies. So that, I think, is the big battle for your generation. Should the government grow, stay the same, shrink? Should the private sector expand, shrink? It's actually a very difficult question. That, I think, is really what you're asking. And I don't have the answer to that. I think it's experience. The mail is a classic example of people in the public sector groups. You're like, oh, well, look at them deliver the mail. We should have FedEx run the world. And then there are other areas where the private sector just seems to be awful. Until electric cars, they just couldn't make a car, like at all. Does that mean maybe the government with some agency should be making cars? That seems a little bit hard to believe. So it's hard to know the right allocation between the private and the public sector. I think that's really what your question is about, and I think your question is better than any answer. I don't think we really know when the agency should expand or shrink. Who else wants to have their question not answered? - Right. So there's been recent discussion sort of reassessing the feasibility of a carbon tax, saying that it's never really politically feasible even though it's a simple rule and it's a lot easier to apply. And some of the arguments that I've heard at least it's never politically feasible, people aren't going to bite for it. And the alternative-- - Why don't you give us the short version of the question? Because I can see people getting a little impatient with all the-- - Yeah, sorry. I guess I'm wondering because it seems like the more complex subsidy is more feasible. Maybe I was wondering if you could talk about the behavioral , behavioral psych, behavioral econ sides of this complexity, simplicity. How's it received? - OK, so I'm going to repeat the question. You're doing a little bit what Epstein does on the other side. So you're picking and choosing your example, which is OK. So if you pick-- I pick military and other examples and patent law. So you're picking carbon tax. It seems like a carbon tax is really a good idea. And therefore, we say, look, that would be very simple, leaving aside what the rate of tax would be, it's not so simple. But wouldn't a carbon tax would be easier than having your massive agency control the environment. Oh, complicated rules are there. There's a simple rule that would seem to be a good idea. I think your question is, well, why don't we have that simple rule? But that might go back to the government and agencies. I mean, the government enjoys having complex rules over there. They get a lot of lobbyists, and they get a lot of interest groups lobbying, oh, let's run the river this way. And let's do that. Let's do that. The private sector, which is controlled by the government there, lobbyists, they don't really want a simple rule because that would take away a lot of the power to alter the government's rules. And the legislators themselves don't really like the carbon tax because that would take away a lot of their power to extract payments from the private sector. Are you with me? So it's a very complicated example. Let's assume the carbon tax would be a good idea. I think it'd probably be a good idea. Epstein would certainly think it was a good idea. So why don't we have a carbon tax? Well, I've given you the solution, I think, which is solution number three in my example. So there are probably many examples like that where we can think of some simple solution that seems like a really good idea. Again, leaving out-- you have to argue about the size of the carbon tax, what to do with other countries that don't have a carbon tax. How do you fix them? It's not so easy to have a carbon tax, but it seems a little bit better than what we have now. I'll give you another example that will give away personal preferences. Why don't we have a guaranteed annual income? That seems so much better than 1,000 different ways of trying to help people who are less fortunate or less well-equipped. Oh, you do a little bit of that, and we fund this. And we forgive loans over there. And then we forgive loans over there. Then we gave tax credits. They only give food stamps. Then we give this-- It's so complicated. There's so many opportunities for fraud and so many opportunities for interest groups to get involved. Why don't we just get rid of a hundred different ways that we try to redistribute income and just give people flat-out money, have some faith that they can run their own lives. It would be so simple to have a guaranteed annual income. Same idea as your question? So again, you can see all the opposition to it. Well, wait a minute, there are all these employees running the thousand ways of internally redistributing the income, they'd all be out of work. They're all going to lobby, don't get rid of me, don't get rid of me. There are all these interest groups that like, oh, food stamps. I can make money doing this. And I get that. And I give it over to this worker. A guaranteed annual income would be very, very simple, but you just don't see a lot of people wanting it. And indeed, somebody runs for president saying I want to do a guaranteed annual income, doesn't say out loud I then want to get rid of 50 other programs. And you guys don't vote for him. You vote for some incredibly old guy. But to people like me, this seems really confusing. I don't want any of you to complain that old White guys are running the world. And then on the other hand, offered a simple rule by a young guy who didn't even have the courage to be White. And then you go, oh, no, no, no. He likes markets. Oh, we can't have him. No, no, no. He didn't go to the University of Chicago undergrad. We can't have him. So it is a little bit like it's very hard to talk people into certain kinds of simple rules. That's why Epstein, a famous libertarian, is unpopular in a way in the press because he is [INAUDIBLE]. Simple rules, like let's get over all this complexity. But I don't think it's a surprise that about why we don't gravitate towards him. OK. Please. - How much do you think, like in the FedEx example-- How much do you think it's about the rule being simple or complex or just that there is an alternative to the government rule? So we could have imagined FedEx being the simple rule if the government were a complex rule, right? - So I'm not sure how to answer this question. Let's try. Imagine that the post office actually had a very complicated pricing. Don't I think some private entity would arise and say, we're going to attract a lot of business because we're going to really be simple? - Right. And so that it wouldn't be so much about whether the rule was-- - Yeah, that's kind of interesting, not that your question wasn't interesting. But that's kind of interesting. I don't think it would work because I have probably more faith in markets than you. But let's try an example. Let's compare government-run parks to Disney World. So Disney World is really pretty complex. You can buy tickets. You get in front of the line. Things have different prices. They sell land around there. It's fairly complex. And their competitor, in some way, is national parks in a sense, or in Chicago, local parks. Most of them are free or virtually free. So the public market is very simple. It's free. It doesn't really control who's going to cause more this or more that and who's going to control animals and not. More or less, it's open. I mean, maybe local parks are a better example. It's just there. It's very, very simple. I think you're-- and that's a good example of the government's simple and the private market more complex. It's price discriminating in an efficient kind of way, efficiant, not inefficient. And I think your question is something lik-- well, could it be the other way around. Imagine that the public parks were very complex. Like, you pay more for how many hours you're staying here. You pay it more if you park your car. You pay it more if you take a picture over there. It could really-- well, that's what Disney World does essentially. It could be very complex. I think your question is, well, if the national parks were very, very complex-- oh, you go drinking on the Point. Oh, $8 for you that time. Three drinks, $21, special discount for you. I mean, that is exactly the way Disney World works. They try to figure out optimal pricing to get more money but also to reduce your consumers-- to increase your consumer surplus and takes some of it away and all that. I think your question says, well, if the parks were very complex-- in the way I just described, somewhat jokingly, but not entirely. Wouldn't the private market then offer Disney World 25 bucks, just come do whatever you want? I don't think so because Disney World would-- maybe Disney World wouldn't exist. But Disney World would still have an incentive to price just above your reservation price. It's not like there's anything to be gained in the private market by offering a one-price system. In fact, all the one-price system will do is there would be long lines at Disney World by all the people who want to pay more than what the fixed price was. And Disney World wouldn't be extracting gain from all the people who want to go to the front of the line. So I don't think it works in flip fashion. I think the private market would always step in to try to do what people want at a price that the public market isn't offering. So I guess that's my answer. I might be wrong, but at least that's my first blush answer. Yeah? - You seem to bring up complex choices that are options that private markets provide is offering some efficiency gain. But reading interviews of CEOs of big companies, they seem to be saying-- - We're obviously not giving you enough homework. [LAUGHTER] You really sit around reading-- - If you were my professor, I wouldn't have time to read this. But they seem to bring up very similar problems, like the CEO of Pepsi Co can't get rid of divisions. And there's a lot of interest groups within it. And that actually a lot of private markets that are very inefficient and also need to be applying Epstein's same rules, that we should be creating-- - OK. So the question is well, wait a minute isn't the private market also have these-- well, I can't remember what they're called, these agency cost problems. It's not so easy to hire and fire people. Well, it's compared to what? Compared to the public market, it's much easier. I mean, CEOs, they're like first year law students in Yale. They're just like whining. I mean, come on. Really? It's like that hard to be CEO and fire people? They do it all the time. So of course, it's to their advantage to come and say, oh, you have no idea how hard my job is. It's really hard. You should pay me another $100 million. It's really a very hard job. I mean, that's absurd. They can fire people. They can move them around. They can promote. They can change prices. So I'm not saying they have a perfectly easy world in a complex world. I'm just saying compared to the government, they have more opportunity to be complex. So I guess I don't buy the initial thing. Moreover, when the government does it-- imagine the government now turning-- say, this example. Imagine the government now turning parks into careful pricing. People would go crazy, and politicians would lose. They wouldn't get reelected. There'll be enough people who would be like, it's really not right or-- what do you guys call it again? Fair. It's not fair. The government said, no, no, no, you don't understand. It's really efficient. We need more people to use the park from 6:00 AM to 9:00 AM. And you're all coming at 11:00 AM. It's too crowded. We want to encourage you to come at the right time, so we change the prices by time of day. People would go nuts. Whereas when the private market does it, everybody is like, oh, yeah, OK. The CEO gets to do it. It's your company, do what you want. If it's not a good idea, other companies will arise, and they will say, oh-- that's I guess your question. Other companies will arise, and they'll say, oh, it's fixed price for everything. Oh, by the way, a special discount if you come at 6am, leave by 9am, sort of like parking in private places. So I think it's just compared to what. And I have a lot of faith. Please. - How does the private right of action fit into this? - Could you expand the question a little bit so that I can summarize it inaccurately? - Would be considered as simple rule, or would be considered market forces [INAUDIBLE]?? - You mean if we had more private lawsuits or fewer? Which way are you going? - [INAUDIBLE] - I'm happy to answer the question. I like the topic. I don't yet see the relationship. Which one do you think of is more complex, more private rights of action, or fewer? - I'm not sure. I was wondering what you think. - OK. Are you about to take an exam and you want me to give you the answer? [LAUGHTER] OK, that's pretty good. OK. So the question is-- I'm going to give my version of the question. It's something like-- well, where do courts fit in on this? The more we allow people to go to court, the more private rights of action-- include more examples. The more people can go to court, is that more complexity in the public sector or more simplicity in the public sector, getting courts involved where the government itself is not involved? Is that fair? Is that a fair version of the question? Oh, well, there are-- I don't know. There are a lot of ways to answer this. One would be going back to the question about agencies. I guess you could think of courts as a kind of agency. They can't be fired. These are lifetime judges. And so we could delegate more things to them. The way to delegate more things to them would be to allow them to hear more cases. The way to do that would be your private rights of action thing-- You don't like the environment? Bring a lawsuit and say, I'm going to say-- currently, the government would say, I'm sorry, you don't understand me. But the rule could be oh, no, no, you can bring a lawsuit saying the police are sleeping under the bridge and not doing a good job. You can bring a lawsuit and say, the environment is going terrible. You guys should be running O'Hare a little bit better. And right now, we don't allow those lawsuits. We think that elected officials, the government will decide who to monitor, who to control, who to put lawsuits against even, and so forth. So one way to make the government bigger in a sense-- I don't know whether simple rule or complex rule. The simplicity would be that anybody could go to court and sue. The complexity would be that courts have to issue rules that themselves might be quite complex. Right? It wouldn't just be winning or losing because people could bring suit after suit after suit varying in the complexity of the solution. Am I getting the question right? - Yeah. - Oh, now, I'm kind of into it. [LAUGHTER] Well, OK. So I'm going to give a non-answer answer. Have you had a course with Professor Easterbrook yet? OK, well. let me describe a course with him, and then I'll tell you my reaction to exactly your question. So Judge Easterbrook, like Judge Posner before him-- and not Judge Wood because she has a different view of private rights of action. I know some of you have her class. But Easterbrook's a really good example. Like when you listen to Easterbrook talk about O'Hare Airport, or listen to Easterbrook talk about the environment. I mean, he's kind of unbelievably well-informed about these things, kind of genius about these things. And you find yourself thinking, like you, wow. If only we could have more private rights of action, people could run to Easterbrook's court. And Easterbrook would say, oh, well, solution to that would be to have a carbon tax that went up to this and this level. And beyond that it would be progressive and far away. And then we'll do an exception. For everything, we can outsource to Bulgaria because they don't have enough pollution. And he would get it right. And he would figure out who can handle pollution. So when you meet Easterbrook and you hear him talk about these topics, you begin to think like, wow. Why are the federal courts holding back? If Easterbrook is normal and we gave more lawsuits to the federal courts, then the world would clearly be a much, much better place. OK. The irony is that Easterbrook would say, it's none of my business. Federal courts should have less control. It's a democracy. And Congress should decide this. And I'm not intervening where Congress hasn't said I can intervene or the Constitution said that I can intervene. So there's a little bit of irony there. Just when you need people-- Chicago graduates, I might add. Just when you need people, you think, wow, if only they ran the world, democracy is like, drunk compared to Easterbrook. I really have this feeling every time I hear him on tele-- You're looking fantastic. You can run the world for me. And then you realize well, not all judges are like that. All you need to do is-- all you need to do is go to like 10 lunch talks at the University of Chicago. And you begin to think like, well, I don't know. [LAUGHTER] Some of these judges are nice people, but I don't know. And maybe democracy is a pretty good thing. It's very complicated like when you want to give things to courts and when you don't and where you think democracy does a good-- Same with the agencies. Some people go work for the government, and they come and say, well, the people working there were really fantastic. Their underling, not so good. So you're not sure how much to assign to various agencies because you don't know if the person you meet who comes to your lunch talks is really good. You don't know what they'll really get to decide things, or they'll have to outsource. And the Internal Revenue Service is a very good example of that. You're just not sure what you want. So I think that's kind of my answer. It's really complicated. The more you thought your judges were really extraordinary, the more you'd like them to have more business. The way to get them more business would be have like, projects [INAUDIBLE].. Let foreigners sue. Who cares? Anybody can bring it to court. We should do that. Immigration policy is a really good example. Should it be run by Congress? Should it be run by an agency? Or should it be run by courts getting really involved? I have no idea. I doubt you have any idea, that's a really complex problem. Probably there are very few citizens who want completely open borders. In my family, I'm the only one. Most people like, no, this just can't be right. Stop thinking of global welfare and all that. Well, would Easterbrook come up with a better rule? Will the Congress come up with a better rule? There'll be some states that would be winners, some states that are losers. So I don't know if private rights of action really do a better job over there. But if you do, the person to get would be Easterbrook I think would be a good rule. But thank you for your question. Please. - I was thinking how you think selective enforcement might-- - What? Selective enforcement. - Selective enforcement might teach the simplicity story. My thought was that it might encourage more like [INAUDIBLE] bargaining. And that might not be what we want. My thought was like a police officer pulled me over on Lakeshore Drive like, oh, officer, you don't understand, my wife's in labor, whatever, whatever. Versus, no, actually we considered all of those exceptions to this rule and you don't fall under any of them. - Yeah, OK. I think I'm getting to understand the question. It's really very similar to our prior question. I don't mean that in a bad way. It's something like, well, if you don't like courts in every situation, maybe what you like is to try to have selective enforcement, like try to have common people be police or common people controlling the environment. And they should be allowed to make exceptions. Same with taxes. Nah, maybe they should figure out whom to audit, when to give a break, when not to give a break. Your example of police is trying [INAUDIBLE] but yeah, you could do this with any areas of law. - I think my question was different. I think my question was-- - It was a good question. First of all, it was a good question. - I think my question was like, if people are going to have selective enforcement in the world, people would probably misbehave. - And that's complexity? - Is it that having a simple rule might facilitate more of that? And that might be a drawback. - Might facilitate more selective enforcement. - Hmm? - You think it might encourage selective enforcement? - I think simple rules might encourage selective enforcement. - I don't really see why that is. - Because-- - I think it'd be the other way around. - Well, my thought was that it's such a simple property right? And so then there's much more scope for bargaining. - Yeah, but the more complex the rule, the more the enforcer has all sorts of ability to move you around along the rules. So I'm not really sure. I think if I were a government official who really like to be in charge of selective enforcement-- when you think about your example, police stop you on the road-- if police want to follow my car-- I am really a pretty careful driver. But if the police want to follow my car, they can probably find 10 violations every minute. There's so many rules. It's so comple-- oh, oh, you're going to cross the line get in to a lane. Oh, you didn't do this. Oh, you didn't see that sign. Oh, there was a vehicle on this side, turned out to be a police officer. You need to move lanes. Ah, you didn't do that. So they have incredible ability to be selectively enforcing. So I don't know which one leads to more selective enforcement. But it is otherwise the same idea. I mean, I'm with you on that. It's the same idea. I think selective enforcing is inevitable. Selective enforcing is kind of funny when you think about it. Can you imagine saying to the military, OK, go invade Iraq. But you decide, you completely decide whom to shoot and when. You know, because you have more information on the ground. Whoa. Like then it seems like the simple rule is really move from top down or something. Like it's not obvious what the right rule is. So it has simple rules like the president decides to invade, and all that. So I don't know. I think it's really very complicated. So I guess my answer is no. I don't-- You mean I don't think simple / complex is related to enforcement. I don't really see the connection. Maybe selective enforcement is just inevitable. I think there is time for one more question. Who has waited the longest to ask a question? Please. - Imagine [INAUDIBLE]-- - What's it like, the last question? You feel powerful? - Yes, I feel very powerful. - OK, then why don't you go? - Imagine the President had you as his shoulder angel, what would you be pushing him to do? [LAUGHTER] You're such a different generation. What does shoulder angel mean? - I don't know, personal advisor, his conscience. I don't know. - Oh. - If I gave you a seat in the Senate tomorrow-- - I understand. You mean do I like-- do I myself like simplicity and complexity? - Would you-- - I don't think you understand-- law school's not about me. It's about you as society. I'm not a normative guy. I'm happy to the answer to the question. I don't know. Like you know-- But OK. Well-- - Another question would be-- - No, I like-- OK, so I'll answer it. [LAUGHTER] I think I like competition between a public and private sector. To me, that's the ultimate question, as discussed earlier. What should the government do? What should the private sector do? So I like things like schools, hospitals, other things, where each sector can watch what the other sector does. And we can evaluate the sector based on how well those compare to the other sector. I like even more-- oh, now I'm going to answering your question. I'll like it even more comparing our performance to other countries. So for example, look at things we do very badly. I'm going to finish with this. So here's a favorite of mine. Think of things we do very badly, meaning we spend a lot of money and we don't get good results. Sometimes we get great results. I'll take university education. We do very, very well. Public schools in Chicago, we do very, very poorly. We spend a huge amount of money, and we do worse than 46 other countries. It's really embarrassing. So health care, we have average life expectancy around the world, but we spend like six times as much money per capita than most other countries. So those are two areas where I would say, uh oh, we're like really in bad shape. So what I would do there is I would go look at the other sector. We don't have that really. I like the competition between entities here. I would go look at countries that are doing very well. In the case of health care, for example, Italy does very, very well, spends much less money than we do. And they have increased life expectancy compared to us. So I would-- now, if I were the government, I would sa-- if I was president, I would say, starting in three years, we're going to do exactly what Italy does. Whatever they do, whatever they pay for, whatever they do, we're going to do the same thing because they're doing a better job. That's what I would do, both competition within the country and competition outside the country. Let's think of what we-- the way they're trying to copy our universities, we should copy their health care and not where we go, oh, American exceptionalism, or nuh nuh nuh nuh you know, like-- Well, thank you so much for coming. Go get lunch. [APPLAUSE]
Info
Channel: University of Chicago Law School
Views: 1,012
Rating: undefined out of 5
Keywords:
Id: 4H7yMdvv3FE
Channel Id: undefined
Length: 65min 24sec (3924 seconds)
Published: Tue Oct 25 2022
Related Videos
Note
Please note that this website is currently a work in progress! Lots of interesting data and statistics to come.